Fibs-die_alfi_kernbericht_130827_final
Final Report
DEVELOPING THE ADULT LEARNING SECTOR
Lot 2: Financing the Adult Learning Sector
(Contract EAC 2012-0073)
Prepared for the European Commission/DG Education and Culture
FiBS – Forschungsinstitut für Bildungs- und Sozialökonomie
DIE – Deutsches Institut für Erwachsenenbildung
Berlin, August 27, 2013
Forschungsinstitut für
Bildungs- und Sozialökonomie
Institute for Education and
Socio-Economic Research
Reinhardtstr. 31 – 10117 Berlin
Tel.: 030/8471223-0 – Fax: 030/8471223-29
E-mail: [email protected]
URL: www.fibs.eu
Deutsches Institut für
Erwachsenenbildung
German Institute for Adult Education
Heinemannstraße 12-14 – 53175 Bonn
Tel.: 0228/3294-0 – Fax: 0228/3294-399
E-mail: [email protected]
URL: www.die-bonn.de
2. Participation rates in adult learning
3. The benefits of adult learning
3.1 Macro-economic benefits
3.2 Micro-economic benefits
3.3 Wider benefits
4. Macro level funding
4.1 Funding volumes
4.2 Funding indicators
4.3 Funding trends over time
4.4 Funding for adult learning in relation to total funding for education
5. Funding systems and instruments and participation in adult learning
6. Financing of certain target groups and learning providers
6.1 Second chance education/basic skil s provision
6.2 Higher education (for the first time) later in life
6.3 Learning of older and retired people
6.4 Funding situation of learning provider
7. Conclusions and recommendations
Annex: Country-specific considerations
List of abbreviations
1. Introduction
Europe is at the cross-roads: the labour market has an increasing need for skil ed
and highly-skil ed labour, while demand for low qualified is shrinking rapidly. At the same time demographic chance and other factors request a later (effective) retirement age. These and other developments wil result in an increasing need for – vocational as wel as non-vocational – adult learning, likely to require additional funding, while spending for education has even decreased in recent years in the aftermath of the economic crisis (Eurydice 2013).
In the light of these chal enges ahead, this study maps and analyses key data, the
sources, the mechanisms of funding approaches and relevant recent developments with a particular focus on the fol owing countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Germany, Estonia, Hungary, Italy, Netherlands, Romania, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, and United Kingdom as wel as Norway and Switzerland as EEA countries and – in order to compare Europe's adult learning policies with those of major competitors – the four non-European countries Australia, Canada, Korea and the USA. Based on a thorough analysis of previous and own research on the financing of adult learning it draws conclusions and recommendations. It aims to enhance knowledge about the effects of funding volumes, systems and instruments on adult learning in general as wel as for certain target groups and areas of adult learning (second chance education/basic skil provision, higher education later in life, older/retired people) and learning providers.
The next section 2 reviews the most recent data on participation rates and is
fol owed by an overview about the wider benefits of adult learning (section 3). Section 4 provides an overview of total spending for adult learning by the various stakeholders, complemented by indicators al owing a comparison of spending levels across countries. Funding systems and instruments and their role in relation to participation are presented and analysed in section 5. This is fol owed by section 6 reviewing the funding policies for the three target groups (second chance education/basic skil s, higher education (for the first time) later in life, older and retired people) as wel the financial conditions of learner providers. Findings are summarised in section 7 and brought forward to conclusions and recommendations.1 The annex provides a brief overview on country-specific aspects.
2. Participation rates in adult learning
New data on participation in adult learning has been published only very recently,
indicating that on average participation rates in EU-27 countries increased between 2007 and 2011 from 35 to 41%, according to Adult Education Survey (AES) (see
1 The Terms of Reference, a detailed overview about the data and methods used and a more detailed
analysis is provided in the annex of this study.
Figure 1).2 This trend emerges also for most countries, though to a varying extent in detail. In Northern, Western and Southern Europe al countries show increasing rates, with one exception in each region (Sweden, Belgium and Greece),3 while the newer member states are split into two groups. The one group (EE, HU4, PL, and RO) reveals increasing rates, while the rates declined in the other (BG, LT, LV, SI, and SK).
Furthermore, many countries show a reduction in participation rates for formal adult
learning which is often over-compensated by increasing rates in non-formal learning. If an increase is visible for both segments, the increase in non-formal learning is commonly higher than for formal learning. This indicates a shift towards more non-formal learning.
Participation rates and mean hours of instruction (AES 2007 and 2011)
Participation rate in 30
Instruction hours 2007
Instruction hours 2011
Source: AES 2007 and 2011
Figure 1: Participation rates and mean hours of instruction according to AES 2007 and 2011
(ranked according to participation rates 2011)
An interesting finding, though, is that many countries with higher participation rates
in 2011 than in 2007 have lower mean hours of instruction in 2011 than in 2007 (see the two bars at the right in Figure 1), while most countries with lower participation rates increased mean hours of instruction; though exceptions exist. For example, BE, SI, LT, LV, and SK show decreases in participation and instruction time. Thus, a trade-off
2 It is likely that this average figure will change slightly since AES 2011-data is not yet readily available
for al countries. Updated data were provided in July 2013, providing the participation rate for the United Kingdom (35.8% compared to 49.3% in 2007) and revising 2011-figures for Switzerland (65.5% instead of 67.2%). As a result average rate goes down from 40.8% to 40.2%.
3 The newly published data for the UK increase the number of exceptions to two for Western Europe. 4 Hungary and France report a break in time series.
between participation rates and mean hours of instruction can be observed in most countries.5
Reviewing participation patterns in relation to educational attainment, the common
trend of participation rates increasing with educational attainment is stil clearly visible. Many countries, e.g. DE, SI, PT and CY, seem to have had a stronger focus on low qualified, whose rates increased more than those for the medium and highly qualified. Figure 2 reveals that the relative difference between the low and the highly qualified is lower in 2011 than in 2007, i.e. the right bar is lower than the leftish one. For example, PL reduced difference from factor 12 to less than factor 9, i.e. the participation rate of highly qualified is 12 and 9-times, respectively, higher than that of low qualified. However, this is not valid for al countries; instead some countries, e.g. CZ, SK, show increasing disparities between the low and highly qualified. The highest level of inequality can be observed in Romania, where high qualified have a 16-times higher probability to participate in adult learning, whereas the difference is only factor two in the Nordic and in several Western European countries. Overal , disparity is higher in the newer member states than in the rest of Europe, apart from Greece and Italy on the one hand and Hungary, Estonia and Bulgaria on the other.
Relative differences between lowest and highest education (AES 2007 and 2011)
Relative difference is calculated by dividing
the participation rate of the high qualified
(ISCED 5=6) by the participation rate of the
low qualified (ISCED 0=2). High values refer to
a large relational distance between high
and low qualification, small values refer to a
small distance between the participation rate of
low and high qualified.
Newer member states
Source: AES 2007 and 2011
Figure 2: Relative differences between lowest and highest education (AES 2007 and 2011).
5 This could suggest to review the European benchmark indicator on adult education for ET 2020, which
is based on participation rates only. An indicator, which combines participation rates and mean hours of instruction might be more appropriate and would al ow a better comparison between countries.
In relation to age, younger age groups, particularly those aged 25 to 34, participate
far more than older cohorts, especial y those aged 55 to 64. However, as for educational attainment, in many countries the rates of older people increased slightly more than those of the younger groups, resulting in lower disparity rates, whereas disparity has increased in some other countries, particularly in Greece and Romania.6
3. The benefits of adult learning
3.1 Macro-economic benefits
Adult learning is beneficial for society, individuals and economy. Coulombe/Trem-
blay/Marchand (2004) found human capital to be a crucial factor in explaining the convergence of GDP per capita over time.7 Their results suggest that growth is mainly fostered by improving the skil s of al society members rather than focusing strictly on skil development of highly talented individuals. Adult education in particular may contribute to a reduction in the gap between the skil s needed by employers and those held by employees and thus increase output (Coel i/Tabasso/Zakirova 2008).
Bivariate estimation results
Correlation
Dependent
Independent
coefficient r
innovation index (2010)
participation in AL (2009)
innovation index (2010)
share of training enterprises as%
innovation index (2010)
innovation index (2010)
employee participation in CVT
innovation index (2010)
Other forms of learning in
enterprises index (2005) (2005)
innovation index (2010)
costs of CVT as % of total labour
*p < 0.05 (significant); **p < 0.01 (highly significant); ***p < 0.001 (extremely significant)
Table 1: CVT provision and participation, and innovation (Cedefop 2012)
As Table 1 reveals, our analyses show strong (bi-variate) correlations between adult
learning and countries' innovation performance indicators. More precisely, the effect of different measures of participation in and provision of training – participation in adult learning (AL), the share of training enterprises, HR practices, employee participation in CVT courses, workplace learning and costs of CVT as share of total labour cost – on innovation performance was analysed. Bivariate estimation results suggest that strong
6 The likelihood to participate in adult learning is now 6.5-times higher for young people; up from 4.5 in
Greece and 5.6 in Romania.
7 Results based on data of the 1994 International Adult Literacy Survey (IALS) on 14 OECD countries
over the time frame 1960 to 1995. Human capital investment measured by average test scores of the population aged 17 to 25 concerning literacy, prose, quantitative or document skil s.
and significant linear relationships exist between al previously stated measures of participation in and provision of training in the EU27 and Norway. Participation in AL hereby shows the highest correlations (r = 0.67) with innovation performance (Cedefop 2012c).8
While the significant correlation between participation in adult learning and
innovation performance could not be confirmed in "smal er" multivariate analyses including the highly significant control variable cognitive factors (i.e. task-complexity aspects of work organisation), a factor analysis accounting for multiple important indicators linked to innovation retrieved interesting results in this regard.
The study used a factor analysis to explore if human capital formation has an actual
effect on innovation performance. To generate the human capital factor, variables representing participation in and provision of adult learning were col apsed in one factor, explaining 66.6% of the variance.
As portrayed by Table 2 the human capital formation factor correlates with share of
training enterprises, employee participation in CVT courses, firms' investment in CVT, participation in AL, workplace learning and the human resources (HR) index. Of the 6 variables col apsed, participation in adult learning (LFS 2009) had the fourth highest loading, after the first three variables related to CVET.
Components (factors)
Human capital formation
Participation in AL (LFS 2009)
Share of training enterprises as% of total (2005)
Employee participation in CVT courses (2005)
Workplace learning index (2005)
Costs of CVT as% of total labour cost (2005)
Table 2: Human capital formation (Cedefop 2012)
Overal , multivariate regression results suggest that task complexity (cognitive
factors) and human capital formation are the two driving factors of innovation performance rather than participation in higher education (HE) (see Table 3), the latter being frequently used as an indicator of innovative ability. Concerning the significant link between the human capital factor and innovation performance, it should be noted that results suggest this link to be strongly driven by CVET variables. Furthermore, the strong significant effect of task complexity on innovation performance portrays the importance of learning-intense (working) environments for innovation. The results of this study clearly highlight the importance of adult learning for innovation in Europe.
8 Additional multi-variate analyses indicate that learning in the workplace (i.e. learning while working)
through task complexity is the most important driver for innovation performance (Cedefop 2012b).
Dependent
Independent
coeffcient
Innovation index (2010) Factor 1 (Organisation typology)
Factor 2 (Human Capital
GDP per capita (2010)
Cognitive factors (al years)
Share of tertiary education
Table 3: Regression results (Cedefop 2012)
According to this Cedefop-study, adult learning is obviously more important for
innovation performance than (initial) higher education, whereas Voßkamp/Nehlsen/ Dohmen (2007) identified a relationship between age, tertiary education and innovation in the sense that the strength of the association between tertiary education and innovation depends on the age of the tertiary educated. Particularly strong links were hereby found between the share of tertiary educated people aged 45 to 54 – and mainly for ISCED 5B, but not for ISCED 5A/6 – and innovation. This could suggest that tertiary education needs to be complemented by (general and/or vocational) adult learning, reconfirming the crucial importance of adult learning for innovation.9
These findings are complemented through a positive relationship between adult
learning and economic growth, which was identified through this study; countries with higher growth rates in 2007 and 2011 show higher AES participation rates in adult learning than countries with lower growth rates. This is valid for cross-sectional analyses and becomes even stronger, if a time-lag model is introduced; i.e. the correlations are stronger for the time-lag model than for the model without. This could be a first indication that participation in adult learning has a positive impact on growth.
Furthermore, the relationship tends to weaken after 3 years, suggesting that adult
learning has a temporary impact and depreciation is taking place; a finding which is in line with expectations as well as with Brunel o (2001), who found that depreciation is taking place for individuals. This observation suggests on the one hand that participation in adult learning is important not only for short-term but also for mid-term growth, though not for long-term growth, unless adult learning is repeated from time to time.10
9 These findings suggest that adult learning should be taken into account for innovation indicators, such
as, for example, the European Union Innovation Scoreboard (UIS). Another issue of the UIS is that input factors are taken into consideration, even though its role for innovation is disputable (Cedefop 2012b).
10 When regarding regression results derived on the basis of simulated data for the entire time frame
2007 till 2011, results of different estimation techniques are less straight-forward. However, the estimation results of nearly all (5 out of 6) models with the comparatively higher goodness of fit values also suggest a positive relationship between participation in adult learning and growth. This serves as additional indication that differences in participation rates in adult learning in Europe may have contributed to differences in growth rates over the past half-decade. This is important since several countries, such as, for example, Germany, increased public spending for adult learning during the crisis, while others did not, but decreased even (Eurydice 2013; see also section 4.3 in this study).
However, even a more cautious interpretation suggests that adult learning plays an
important role in relation to economic performance: the results in this study show that companies are an important driver for participation in adult learning. If employer act economical y rationale, their investment in adult learning and continuing vocational education and training is important in relation to their economic development, i.e. they would not invest if they would not benefit from it. Thus, the higher participation rates in adult learning in economical y more advanced countries are necessary in order to support these higher growth (and innovation) rates. This argument is also supported by lower rates of return to adult learning (e.g. higher education) in economical y more advanced countries.
3.2 Micro-economic benefits
At individual level, several studies show income benefits and reduced unemploy-
ment rates for adult learners (e.g. Lynch 1994; Brunel o/Comi/Sonedda 2010; Brunel o 2001; Murray/Skarlind 2005; Zhang/Palameta 2006).11 The results vary from an increase of hourly wages by 0.2% for one week of training (Lynch 1994) to a 2% wage increase after one day of training. According to Brunel o/Comi/Sonedda (2010), the literature finds wage returns of a least 3% for one week of (private sector) training, a finding which they confirm with regard to selected Italian regions, where returns were estimated at 4.4%, though confronted with high depreciation rates. The varying size is also due to heterogeneity of adult learning itself. However, it should also be understood that the returns are not measured in relation to the costs of adult learning but in relation to the previous wage; due to the commonly rather limited costs of adult learning it is likely that rates of returns in relation to costs are comparably high.12 Yet, this needs further investigation, which also applies to the long-term benefits of adult learning.13
Another finding with regard to the economic crisis Europe faced over the last few
years (and stil faces) is, that the correlation between training participation and initial education is even increasing, "when European economies are hit by negative temporary shocks" (Brunel o 2001, p. 15). Thus, those with less education are hit threefold by an economic downturn: (1) their risk of unemployment is higher, (2) qualification requirements for employment increase, and (3) they participate less in adult education and further training than those with higher educational attainment.
However, such relationships are commonly not valid in any case. For example, even though DK increased public funding for and participation rates in adult learning it shows a negative growth rate in GDP per capita between 2007 and 2012, whereas LT shows positive growth rates, despite declining public funding amounts and participation rates. However, it would be advantageous to have more frequent data on partication rates.
11 However, discussions still prevail to what extent such returns are due to adult learning or training or
due to other, unobserved factors (e.g. Messer et al. 2010; Oosterbeek 2013).
12 A simple il ustration might support this view: If costs for adult learning are € 2,000 (which is a rather
high amount) and the wage increase is e.g. € 30 per month over three years, the rate of return would be 4.4%.
13 It appears that the long-term benefits are higher than the short-term benefits (e.g. Kruppe 2013).
Since this can also be observed for the recent crisis, better educated people are less hit by the crisis, resulting, in fact, in increasing returns. Statistics show that the unemployment rates of people with higher education rose to a much lower extent fol owing the economic crisis, namely from 3.3% to 4.7% between 2008 and 2010, than for people without or with upper secondary education. In comparison, the unemployment rate of the prior group rose from 8.8 to 12.5%, the unemployment rate of the latter group from 4.9 to 7.6% during the recession. Overal , having or investing in more education gives individuals an advantage, as it al ows them to remain in their employment positions or change these more easily (OECD 2012).
Furthermore, substantial public and private (monetary) rates of return for second
chance as wel as for higher education later in life as wel as for initial secondary and tertiary education can be identified (e.g. OECD 2008, 2012 as wel as sections 6.1 and 6.2). Importantly, public and private rates of return vary a lot across countries and for both sexes; so that it is almost impossible to arrive at general and overarching results, but it appears that returns to education are lower in the Nordic countries than in the other regions. Our research indicates that returns are higher in countries where unemployment is lower. Importantly, private as wel as public rates of return for second chance and higher education later in life are sometimes even higher than for initial education. Though further research, particularly for Europe(an countries) is needed in order to arrive at more conclusive results, these findings provide some room to chal enge the common line of argumentation as regards decreasing rates of returns across the life-span (see in this direction also Käpplinger/Haberzeth/Kulmus 2013).
Equal y important with regard to policy advice is that returns to adult education arrive
much faster than for initial education. This provides room to argue, firstly, that investments in adult learning should be kept high or even increased. Secondly, it can also suggest to invest in adult and higher education first and to use the earlier (fiscal) returns to boost investments in early childhood and school education slightly later. The opposite strategy, i.e. to invest in early education first, wil result in measurable (fiscal) return only from 2035 onwards (Dohmen 2011; Dohmen/Henke 2011).
3.3 Wider benefits
Apart from such economic benefits, wider benefits on health, crime and social
cohesion can be observed. Individuals become less depressive, more self-reliant and resilient, stop smoking and drug and alcohol abuse. The starting point of such analysis is the basic model for the wider benefits of learning (see Figure 3), in which education impacts via the mediating mechanisms ‘skil s, beliefs and competencies', ‘social interactions' and ‘qualifications' on the wider benefits.
Social productivity
• Individual health,
• Skills, beliefs,
• Family functioning
• Social interactions
• Qualifications
• Social cohesion,
Source: Feinstein/Sabates 2007
Figure 3: A simple model for the wider benefits of learning (Feinstein/Sabates 2007).
One of the core messages by Feinstein and Sabates (2007) is that in addition to
qualification is a key currency for the labour market, adult learning has far more effects on individuals and several of those are even more important for society as wel as for economic growth and social cohesion. Such "social productivity" may on the one hand sustain positive developmental trajectories and generate positive life chances, on the other hand it may prevent aspects leading to personal and social dislocation (individual exclusion, community breakdown), such as obesity, crime, teenage parenthood, anti-social behaviour, intolerance, mental health problems, social division, disengagement, drug abuse and social immobility. The returns to adult learning are visible irrespective of whether young or mature adults are concerned (Feinstein/Sabates 2007; Connol y/Rees/Furlong 2008):
Women enhance their chances of re-entering the labour market, if they gain
qualifications during adulthood (Jenkins et al. 2003; Jenkins 2006), and reduce their dependence from welfare benefits.
The costs of poverty crime in England and Wales would be reduced by between
£10m and £320m per year if 1% of the working age population gains level 2 (instead of no) qualification. Raising it further to level 3 would save another £70m and £180m. If this spreads over to other forms of crime total saving would be £665m p.a. in England and Wales (Feinstein 2002a).
Bringing 1% of people with no qualification to level 1 would reduce risk of
depression among women by 6 to 10 percentage points and for younger men by 6 percentage points. This would result in savings of treatment costs of about £6 to £34m if 10% of women would increase their qualifications to level 1. Raising the level further up to level 2 would even reduce probability of depression at age 42 by 15% from 26% to 22%; this would save £200m (Feinstein 2002b; Feinstein/Chevalier 2006).
Fol owing Feinstein/Hammond (2004), adults participating in one or two learning
activities between age 33 and 42 are significantly more likely to stop smoking (reduction of 12.5%), to increase level of exercises (20%) and reported higher life satisfaction (14% reduction of general decline of life satisfaction). Other effects are lower probability of depression or higher recovery rates as wel as to "positive transformations in wel being, optimism, efficacy (perceived control over important factors) and self-rated health" (Feinstein/Hammond 2006; Feinstein/Sabates 2007).
In addition, reduced alcohol consumption and probability of depression as wel as
higher recovery rates are reported. In this regard, the impact of leisure courses is more pronounced than of those related to work. However, al forms (academic accredited, vocational accredited, work-related and learning for leisure) show effects.
Research also reports changes in social and political attitudes, e.g. higher tolerance
levels (one third), lower authoritarian levels, reduced political cynicism and increased political interest, increased membership in organisations and increased participation in elections (Feinstein/Hammond 2004).
Another important aspect is that people with disappointing learning experiences in
youth can change their negative attitude towards learning if they experience positive examples, linking them also to other social networks. According to Feinstein/Hammond (2006), participants in adult education "have positive transformations in wel being, optimism, efficacy (perceived control over important factors) and self-rated health" (Feinstein/Sabates 2007).
Some of the changes in attitudes should be regarded in the light that mid-age adults
commonly are very reluctant to change behaviour; suggesting that even comparatively smal figures are in fact quite substantial in relative terms (see also Field 2012). With regard to various forms of adult learning, Feinstein and Hammond (2004) report that almost al forms of courses (academic accredited, vocational accredited, work-related and learning for leisure) reveal positive effects, possibly with the exception of the vocational programmes leading to accreditation. However, it appears that political and social attitudes are better addressed by academic courses, while leisure courses and work-related training impact on a broader range of outcomes (Feinstein/Sabates 2007).
Furthermore, even low qualified learners with poor learning experiences gain from
positive experiences and proceed with additional learning. Eventual y and often neglected are intergenerational returns when children benefit from their parents' learning (Cedefop 2011). Although the wider benefits are visible, it appears that further efforts are needed to translate the effects into measurable rates of return at macro-level, e.g. what is the impact on public budgets, if people stop smoking, drug and alcohol abuse or become less depressive. However, a first and cautious estimate of the wider benefits mentioned above would easily arrive at least at around € 2 to 3bn per annum for a country like the UK; this is roughly equivalent to 0.1%, possibly even 0.2% of GDP, which is close to the level of public funding in several countries, e.g. the UK (see section 4). Furthermore, even employers benefit from non-vocational adult
learning, e.g. through lower absence rates, because of better health, or better language proficiency; these benefits are not included in the estimation above.
Looking more on non-vocational adult learning, a second model of wider benefits
from Manninen (2012, 2013) refers more explicitly to non-vocational or liberal adult learning and education (see Figure 4).
Participation in liberal
adult education courses
BENEFITS RELATED TO LEARNING PROCESSES
Sense of community, Social interaction, Self fulfillment & Joy of doing
SKILLS AND COMPETENCES
Concrete benefits joy of learning
ADDITIONAL BENEFITS
Travel andforeign cultures
Further education
Wider life circles
Staying uptadated
Instrumental benefits
Motivation to learn
General knowledge
Confidence in own skills
Self=expression and creativity
Change of attitudes
Motivating others to learn
Mental and physical well=being
Well=being at work
Source: Manninen 2012
Participation in society
Figure 4: Manninen's model of wider benefits of liberal adult education (Manninen 2012, 2013).
Testing this model empirical y in several studies (see for an overview Manninen
2010, 2012, 2013; Motschilnig 2012), the relationship between adult education and active citizenship and societal involvement as wel as development of social networks, self confidence etc. (see Figure 4) appears wel established and confirmed. Another very important result concerns the role of many competencies learnt through liberal adult education at the workplace, confirming the blurred or blurring demarcation line between liberal (non-vocational) and vocational adult learning.
More in detail, Manninen's studies (2010, 2012, 2013) found that 28% of
respondents reported spontaneously mental wel -being and 13% improved health as result of liberal adult education. Another important aspect concerns the positive impact of adult learning for additional (sub-sequent) learning, which is noted by almost al participants (98%). Eventual y, Manninen (2012) relates the wider benefits of adult learning to societal chal enges (see Table 4).
Furthermore, recently developed valuation techniques al ow to quantify the returns
to non-market goods such as education in monetary terms (Fujiwara/Campbel 2011). Fujiwara (2012) uses this wel -being valuation approach to value the positive impact of participation in part-time courses on health (£148), the probability to find or keep a job
(£224), social relationships (£658) and volunteering on a regular basis (£130) for the individual. As portrayed by the monetary values, the study finds strong evidence for the benefits and high valuation of adult learning on multiple areas of life, above all concerning social relationships.
What people get from liberal Adult Education?
Language skil s, Cultural competencies
Sense of community, Societal involvement
Networks, Self-confidence
Learning motivation, Confidence on own skil s, Joy of
learning, Learning skil s
Practical skil s, ICT skil s, General knowledge, Wel being at
Physical wellbeing
Mental wellbeing, Wel being at work & daily life, Life quality
Table 4: Wider benefits of learning and societal challenges (Manninen 2012)
Many other publications have sought to create a calculation base for the returns to
(adult) learning, amongst others accounting for their indirect positive effects on safety and democracy, resulting in the assumption that the returns to education have a great economic influence and possibly a larger monetary value than tax returns and social insurance pensions (McMahon 1999, Haveman/ Wolfe 1984). This assumption was confirmed in the study of McMahon (2009). McMahon advocates the incorporation of social activities of graduates in such calculations, as graduates represent the societal group engaged the most in politics and hence – to a large part – contribute to sustaining society.
Summarising the previous results concerning the various benefits and their
distribution across stakeholders it is evident that individuals, employers and society, including the public purse, benefit from (non-vocational) adult learning. In general, this suggests that al three should also participate in funding; probably, individuals and the state more than employers, unless vocational and company training is included; furthermore, employment agencies, if applicable, are very likely to be a major beneficiary and should contribute to the financing, not only for the unemployed but also for low qualified. However, it is difficult to establish exact ratios how much each beneficiary should contribute.
4. Macro level funding
4.1 Funding volumes
This study arrives, for the first-time ever, at (roughly) comparable spending figures
for adult learning for a relevant number of countries.14 Furthermore, it is important to note that the understanding of adult learning varies across countries; the figures presented in this study are therefore not necessarily identical with figures from other sources.15
Expenditures for Adult Learning in % of GDP (ALE for age 25+ (adjusted))
Source: own calculations; sources see annex
Figure 5: Adjusted spending for adult learning (age 25+, excl. higher education) in % of GDP16
14 For details on the sources and methodological aspects of this chapter see section 8 in the annex, in
particular section 8.2.
15 For example, spending for post-compulsory education in the UK is almost 4% (Schul er/Watson 2009),
since this includes initial higher education, going down to 0.7% for adult learning according to our estimations. In this study, we distinguish between adult learning for those aged 25+ (exclusive of higher education) on the one hand and adult learning including of higher education for mature students, aged 25 and above.
16 As mentioned more in detail in section 8.2 in the annex, availability of funding data is rather limited
and based on various definitions etc. Several countries estimate funding figures only once upon a time (e.g. Switzerland for 2007 and UK for 2008), other countries report some data on an annual basis, e.g. Germany, while some data are col ected only every few years, e.g. bi- or three-annual y, and either estimated for the time in between these collections. This leaves us with two options: (1) to have data for one or two years, e.g. 2009 and/or 2010, for (even) fewer countries or (2) to provide data for more countries at the cost of comparability for some countries, while accepting limitations in comparability because of various years. We opted for the latter, because it seems likely that figures do not change extremely, despite the crisis. However, limited comparability of data for CH and UK should be taken into consideration.
Countries like AT, DK and SE spend more than 1.2% of GDP (countries in Figure 5
are ranked according to AES participation rate 2011)17; NO almost 1.2%. CH and NL spend between 1.0 and 1.1% of GDP. Several countries al ocate between 0.8 and 1.0% of GDP for adult learning, HU, SI, DE18, and FI. Eventual y, EE, SK19 and the UK spend around 0.7% of GDP, while ES is at about 0.5%20. CA and AU seem to spend even less, though this may be due to under-reporting. Two different figures are presented for the USA, due to different estimates concerning employer spending on training. While the ASTD estimates spending to $ 1,086 per employee, adding up to 0.9% of GDP, another more conservative estimate from Wilson (2010) suggests an employer spending of 0.4% of GDP. Consequently, total spending varies between 1.1% and less than 0.6% of GDP.21 22
An important finding in Figure 5 is that spending volumes appear to be linked to
participation rates according to AES 2011. Al five countries with the highest rates, SE, CH, NO, NL, and DK spend more than 1.0% of GDP, FI spends slightly less, but had also lower participation rates in 2007. This could suggest that a spending level of (almost) 1.0% of GDP is required to arrive at a participation rate of at least (almost) 60%; the only other countries with such high funding volumes but lower participation rates are AT and the US (ASTD), pointing to possible inefficiencies (see in this regard also Lassnigg et al. 2013). The vast majority of countries with participation rates of up to 50% spend between 0.6 and 0.8%, exceptions in addition to AT and US (ASTD) are DE and SI; the latter may also have room for increasing effectiveness, though it should be noted that funding decreased recently.23
Because no data on participation rates for 2011 are yet available for FI, UK, US, CA and AU, these
figures remain identical with 2007 data.
17 AES 2011 participation rates for UK were not yet published when the figure was prepared; the recently
published data indicate a drop from almost 50% in 2007 to 36% in 2011, which would mean that UK is the country with the lowest participation rate among the countries considered here.
18 Spending level for DE would go up 1.2% of GDP is budget for active labour market policy is increased
to the levels mentioned in Eurydice (2013), while this level of 0.9% results on the basis of published data from the Federal Statistical Office, adjusted by own estimates for individual and company spending (see methodological remarks in section 8.2 of the annex).
19 With regard to SK, the basis for this estimate is somewhat limited, since the data for 2009 and 2010
arrive at completely different average figures per participant, suggesting that the final figures may lie somewhere in between.
20 Spending in Spain may be (slightly) underreported as no data for public funding is yet available (May
21 This example show how important reliable funding data is and that it is sometimes difficult to assess
which data is more appropriate – or plausible – than others.
22 When including spending for mature students in higher education spending goes up, though at varying
rates, depending on the share of mature students enrolled in universities and the level of tuition fees and public spending. The first group of countries, comprising the USA (ASTD), DK and SE, spends more than 2% of GDP. Another three countries, FI, NO, and AT, spend between 1.8 and 1.7%. Seven countries al ocate between 1.5 and 1.0% of GDP for adult learning, in descending order US (Wilson 2010), NL, UK, SI, DE, CH and AU. Eventually, five coutries appropriate less than 1% of GDP, ES, HU, CA, EE, and SK.
23 Analyses on the basis of AES in combination with funding data for selected years only does not allow
to assess the intermediate link between changes in funding and participation. However, as the LFS provides participation data for each year, a preliminary review of participation rates and funding
Though (bi-variate) statistical analyses show a significant correlation between total
spending in relation to GDP and participation rates, according to AES 2011, this disappears when control ing for GDP per capita.24
Reviewing funding volumes by financier, employers bear the biggest part in most
countries, apart from NO, FI and SE, where the state contributes more (in FI only if funding from employment agency is included25). In most countries, the employers' share is around 0.4 to 0.5% of GDP, in some countries, such as DK, the NL and US (ASTD) it is even more. In contrast, the state contributes only 0.1 to 0.2% of GDP, except in the Nordic countries, where it is at least 0.4%. The share of funding from individuals lies in between employer and state funding in most countries, with 0.2 to 0.3% of GDP. ESF funding is reported differently across countries; in some it is explicitly counted as ‘other', in others it is part of state funding.
Distribution of funding for adult learning by financier (ALE for age 25+ adjusted)
Source: own calculations;
Employment Agency
sources see annex
Figure 6: Distribution of funding between stakeholders for adult learning (aged 25+ - adjusted)
(ranked according to AES 2007 participation rate)
volumes suggests that decreasing (public) funds are likely to result in lower participation, as the examples SI and DK illustrate. However, both indications do not necessarily develop in the same direction.
24 It may stil have to be seen, whether the inclusion of funding data for more countries results in
significant correlations; actually, funding and participation data (2011) at the same time is only available for 12 (exclusively European) countries.
25 From our point of view, employment agencies should be considered separately from state funding, as
its funding sources vary across country. While employment agencies are funded from the public budget in some countries, employer and employee funding, in the form of social security/insurance contributions, are the major sources in other countries, e.g. Germany.
Looking at the distribution of funding between stakeholders more explicitly (see
Figure 6), employers bear almost or even more than half of total spending in a majority of 10 countries, which is the case for state funding only in AU and NO. Individuals contribute the largest share in CH with 44%, commonly it is between 15 and 30%.26
Relating this distribution of funding to the distribution of benefits, as elaborated in
the previous section, it appears that individuals contribute less than might be appropriate, while employers may pay more than expected, at least according to the benefits. However, since the focus of this study is not on company training, which is likely at the core of employer funding, this share may be justified because of the employers' benefits from company training.
Reviewing the macro level links between participation and distribution of funding
more in detail, it seems that the participation rate is higher in countries where individuals bear a smal er share, while the joint state-employer share is higher (if applicable, including employment agencies). However, statistical analyses suggest some caution, although some preliminary findings turn up.
Total funding as per cent of GDP as wel as state funding in relation to GDP
correlate statistical y significantly and positive with AES 2011 total participation rate, though this link vanishes when control ing for GDP. Total funding as per cent of GDP is also statistical y significant and positive linked to non-formal adult learning (AES 2011)27 as wel as total participation according to LFS 2010 and LFS 2011.
Some other links show weakly significant or only almost significant correlations, e.g.
concerning the state's funding share in relation to total (formal or non-formal) participation, according to AES/OECD 200728, and formal adult learning in OECD countries 2007 (OECD 2012)29. The only link with regard to funding from individuals at macro level is a weakly significant and negative correlation for formal adult learning (according to AES 2011). Since the micro economic analysis later in this section will reveal a stronger negative correlation, this could suggest that average funding per individual in relation to GDP per capita is more important than macro-level funding.
Eventual y, some weakly significant and negative indications can be found
concerning the funding share of employers. However, as for al this analyses, findings should be considered preliminary and request further investigation with enhanced and extended data, i.e. broader country coverage, particularly concerning funding data.
26 If spending for post-24 higher education is included, funding shares of individuals and, particularly, the
state go up and that of employers' decreases, as they are commonly not (much) involved in the financing of higher education. The size of the increase depends mainly on the share of mature students and the level of tuition fees.
27 The relationship between state funding and participation in formal adult learning is almost significant,
while the relationship to non-formal participation rates for OECD countries (OECD 2012) is weakly significant.
28 AES/OECD 2007 combines data from AES 2007 and data from OECD (2012) for the non-European
countries, referring also to the year 2007.
29 The link is only almost significant for AES 2011 participation rates in formal adult learning.
Overal , it appears that funding and participation according to AES 2011 correlate far more to each other than previous surveys.
Adding up, our – though stil preliminary – results show repeatedly that higher
funding and higher state funding, both in relation to GDP and possibly also in relation to funding from other sources, is linked to higher participation rates in adult learning, while it seems that individuals' and employers' share is linked negatively with higher participation rates, i.e. higher participation is linked to lower contributions from employers and individuals; however, this is likely to go at the costs of windfal profits and deadweight loss30, because particularly better educated individuals would invest in adult learning even without public funding (e.g. Messer/Wolter 2009; Falch/Oosterbeek 2011; Oosterbeek 2013; Dohmen 2007).
4.2 Funding indicators
Additional indicators were established in the context of this study in order to al ow
further comparisons on funding across countries. For example, spending per adult concerns the amount spent per adult aged 25 to 64 (independent from whether s/he participates in adult learning or not). This indicator shows important disparities across countries (see Figure 7). For example, NO spends around € 925 per adult (exclusive of post-24 higher education), while AT, SE, DK, the NL and CH (in descending order) spend between € 720 and € 650. The next group comprises FI, DE, and UK with between € 510 and € 410 per adult. EE has the lowest amounts, with around € 130 and even € 100 lower than ES, HU and SK.
A statistical analysis of the relationship between funding per adult and participation
rates reveals significant correlations, suggesting that funding per adult is higher in countries with high participation rates, while very low in countries at the lower ends.31 The pattern becomes even more conclusive, when taking into account the higher participation rates in DK and CH according to AES 2011.32
A second new indicator is spending per adult and per mean hour of instruction (AES
2011), i.e. the number of adults is multiplied by the number of mean hours of instruction; this indicator aims to balance variations in the mean hours of instruction across countries (see Figure 1 in this regard). The corresponding figures (see Figure 8) indicate rather different amounts of money, ranging from € 13, € 14 and € 17 in HU, EE and ES to more than € 90 in NO, which is around 25% more than for UK, AT and SE.
30 Windfall profits and deadweight loss are two sides of the same coin: windfall profits concern the
beneficiaries, who receive public support even though they would have been willing to invest, while deadweight loss refers to the public view, whose financial support does not result in increased participation rates, as beneficiaries would have participated in adult learning even without public subsidies. Thus, both terms can be used almost synonymously.
31 The links are only weakly significant for the relationship between participation rates in adult learning
and the funding amounts per adults borne by the state, the individuals and the employer.
32 It remains to be seen whether this is also valid with regard to the UK , whose participation rate
decreased from almost 50% in 2007 to 35.8% in 2011.
Four countries, DK, FI, DE and SI spend between € 40 and € 50 per adult, while SK arrives at € 30. The overal pattern is that countries with high(er) participation rates spend more per adult and hour of instruction than countries with lower rates. With very few exceptions the line, presenting the AES 2011 participation rates, fol ows almost exactly the spending per adult and hour of instruction. Though statistical y, several (bi-variate) correlations turn up, this needs further investigation.
Spending per adult (aged 25=64) (est.)
Participation rate (A
Spending per adult in Euro (PPS)
Funding per adult (age 25=64) adjusted
Funding per adult (age 25=64) incl. HE (adjusted)
Figure 7: Spending per adult (ranked according to AES 2007 participation rate)
Reviewing the individual's costs per hour of instruction as third indicator (see Figure
9) reveals that individuals pay lower amounts per hour in countries with higher participation rates than in the countries with lower rates. This is particularly the case for formal adult learning (and becomes even more pronounced when the outlier Cyprus, with extremely high costs per hour, is removed). Statistical y, this indicator costs per hour of instruction shows significant negative correlations with participation rates in formal adult learning, according to AES 2011, but also OECD (2012) for the year 2007, even after control ing for GDP as core explanatory factor of participation rates.
Spending per adult and hour of instruction for adult learning in relation to participation rate
pending per adult and hour in E
No AES 2011 data available for FI
Figure 8: Costs per hour of instruction and adult (unit costs).
Average costs per hour of instruction (in Euro PPS) and AES 2007 participation rate in formal
Participation rate in form
Average costs per hour (Euro PPS)
Figure 9: Average costs per hour of formal adult learning in Euro (PPS) and AES 2007
participation rate.
Eventual y, reviewing distribution of spending per adult by financier (see Figure 10),
combined spending of state and employers as wel as funding from each of these two sources separately is far higher in high participation countries compared to countries
with low participation rates (with the mere exception of Switzerland), suggesting that both play a vitale role in explaining differences in participation rates across countries. Although even individuals' spending is higher in countries with higher participation rates, the difference is comparatively smal . Individuals pay between € 110 and € 120, in the countries at the top (apart from Switzerland and Norway).
Furthermore, it is of interest to note that the spending amount per adult coming from
individuals themselves decreases the higher the participation rates among the newer member states are (see the countries on the left-hand side in Figure 10), i.e. the amount individuals spend on average per adult is lower in countries with higher participation rates. The same pattern emerges also for the other, economical y better-off countries. Individuals spend more per adult in AT and DE compared to al Nordic countries, but NO, and the Netherlands, whose participation rates are much higher (see Figure 10) (FI's AES 2011 participation rate is not yet available) (CH remains the second exception, where costs per adult borne by individuals is higher than in better-off countries with lower participation rates).
Distribution of costs per adult by financiers
Figure 10: Distribution of costs per adult by financiers (ranked by participation rate, AES 2011).
4.3 Funding trends over time
Reviewing funding trends over the last few years, available data, which is very
scarce, indicates that some states, such as e.g. DE and DK increased spending during crisis, and reduced it afterwards at least partial y, e.g. DK (Eurydice 2013), while other countries, e.g. HU, SI or UK, reduced particularly state funds in more recent years. A striking finding, though, is that some countries received obviously more EU-funding
(Eurydice 2013), but show lower participation rates (LT, LV) (AES 2011). It is important to note that patterns do not go in the same direction over years, e.g. DK increased public spending in 2009 and reduced it the fol owing year 2010, though stil remaining above the starting point in 2008. This example indicates that it is difficult to talk about trends. It is even political y advisable to increase funding in times of crisis and to reduce it afterwards.
When reviewing the developments in funding amounts during the crisis, a downward
trend can be observed in those countries where participation rates are (much) lower than in the better-off countries, while many better-off countries increased its spending volumes even, at least temporaril y. Since the review of the benefits of adult learning indicated that adult learning has positive effects on growth and innovation, this could mean that economic development may drift apart in the near future, contributing to a widening gap between the worse-off and the better-off countries. This suggests that the ESF's role in fostering (socio)-economic development should be reviewed with the aim to help particularly those countries obviously in need of EU support, without relaxing the requirements for national (public) funding.
4.4 Funding for adult learning in relation to total funding for education
Comparing spending for adult learning with spending for other education sectors
reveals a level between early childhood education, catering to 3 to 5 year olds, and higher education; overal adult learning accounts for 15 to 20% of al education spending in almost al countries, for which we were able to estimate funding figures.
Expenditures for education as percentage of GDP 2009
Pre=primary education (for children aged 3 and older)
Primary and lower secondary education
Upper secondary education
Post=secondary non=tertiary education
Source: OECD 2012; own calculations for adult
Tertiary education
Figure 11: Expenditures for education as percentage of GDP 2009 by education sector
(alphabetical order).
Figure 11 adds the spending volumes for adult learning to the overal spending
figures for education and shows – unsurprisingly – that spending levels go up. Importantly, spending figures increase more in countries with higher spending figures than in those countries with lower spending figures. This indicates that spending for adult learning fol ows the same pattern than for education in general.
5. Funding systems and instruments and participation in adult
learning
Costs are a barrier to participation in adult learning, though its importance differs a
lot across regions and countries as wel as for target groups. This is valid even though the reason ‘training was too expensive or unaffordable' is ranked only fifth, according to AES 2011 – no need for training because of job or, alternatively, private reasons on the one hand and time because of family or work obligations, respectively on the other hand are more important.33
Obstacles to participation in lifelong learning:
Training was too expensive or respondent could not afford it (AES 2011) in %, by sex
Figure 12: Obstacle – Training was too expensive or respondent could not afford it (AES 2011)
in % by sex (ranked according to relevance of costs/affordability as barrier)
Overal , the share of non-participants in adult learning mentioning "training as too
expensive or inaffordability" is 13%. The highest values can be found in Romania, where more than half of non-participants mention this obstacle. Second highest are the
33 A similar result turned up according to AES 2007, even though the indicators "no need because of job"
and "need need because of family" were not yet included; however, these newly introduced indicators affect comparisons between both AES surveys.
values in Switzerland and Greece with close to 30%, fol owed by Estonia, Italy, Netherlands, Latvia and Lithuania with almost 20%. In contrast, the lowest figures come from Slovakia, Belgium and three Southern European countries (Portugal, Spain and Malta).
AES 2011 shows also that more women rather than men state that training was too
expensive or unaffordable (see Figure 12); only Romanian men report higher rates than women. Furthermore, the gender difference is particularly large, in absolute and relative terms, for Switzerland and the Netherlands (9.5 and 10.3 percentage points, respectively), while it is rather smal in Belgium (0.5 percentage points). Large differences can also be found in the newer member states, such as, for example, Estonia, Lithuania and Latvia where women experience more financial restrictions with regard to adult learning. In Southern Europe, these differences do not seem to be as significant (maximum deviation of 5.5% in Italy).
The funding systems vary a lot across the countries reviewed more in-depth in this
study. Among the 20 countries at the core of this study (see section 1 for a list of the so-cal ed ALFi-countries34), 333 funding instruments, available for the financing of non-vocational adult learning,35 can be identified, of which 178 are cost-sharing and 155 are ful y publicly funding.36 For al 33 countries the number increases to 384 (208 cost-sharing and 176 public funding, respectively). Summarising the number of schemes by instrument type, the most important are:
126 supply-side funding instruments across the 20 ALFi-countries (146 across al 33
countries), of which 46 (66) are unconditional and 80 (80) are conditional;37
93 (99) cost-sharing vouchers38, spread over 12 (17) countries.
43 (63) training leave regulations, spread over 16 and 27 countries, respectively;
36 (37) loan schemes (of which 26 are from CH only), spread over 9 and 10
countries, respectively;
24 (25) 100% grants, which require no individual co-financing, in 9 and 10 countries,
5 (8) tax incentives in 5 (8) countries
34 ALFi is the acronym for this study and will be used throughout the report to distinguish between certain
groups of countries.
35 It should be noted, though, that the demarcation between vocational and non-vocational adult
education or whether non-vocational adult learning can be financed by a funding instrument is often not easy to establish.
36 However, it is often difficult to establish exactly, whether an instrument which is labelled as ‘100%
public funding' is really completely public funding or whether (private) co-financing is, in fact, taking place.
37 Information on existence of conditional supply-side funding - as well as for 100% grants and fee
reduction - is only available for the 20 countries investigated in this study.
38 With regard to terminology, in this study vouchers concerns cost-sharing, while grants stands for 100%
publicly funded grants, where no co-financing is required from the individual. However, instrument may cover 100% for certain target groups and less for others or cover 100% for learning programmes with low costs, e.g. up to € 100 or sometimes even € 600 in the Swiss canton of Geneva), while individuals have to pay the remaining amount, if costs are above this threshold.
5 fee reduction/redemption regulations in 2 countries
1 saving schemes.
Looking at regional differences, only few patterns turn up at this stage. While almost
al European countries employ training leaves, they seem to be rather uncommon in the non-European countries covered by this study. In contrast, cost-sharing vouchers are available in all non-European countries, but only in some European countries; where 100% grants are often in place, suggesting that 100% grants and co-financing vouchers are employed complementarily to each other. Although the list suggests a high number of loan schemes, it is worth mentioning that ‘real CVET-loans' are hardly available. Only DE, AU, UK and SE employ loans explicitly for vocational adult learning (AT has a combination of savings and loan scheme), the other loan schemes are for higher education. This finding may be important as (bi-variate) statistical analyses find several correlations between loans and adult learning participation; e.g. with regard to participation in overal (formal and non-formal) as wel as in non-formal AL (according to AES/OECD 2007 as wel as AES 2011 participation rates). In al cases, correlation is stronger and shows higher levels of significance for CVET-loans, rather than for loans in general.39 In contrast, the existence of vouchers shows a weakly significant correlation with regard to non-formal, non-vocational AL participation rates, while tax incentives correlate weakly significant with formal adult learning, which also applies to 100% grants. These results are plausible, by and large: (1) loans al ow financing of more expensive adult learning and tax incentives real cost-sharing between individuals and the state,40 (2) 100% grants play an important role for disadvantaged groups and second chance education, while (3) vouchers, which are commonly limited to smal er amounts, co-finance the much lower costs of non-formal non vocational learning (according to OECD 2007 participation rates). Even though hard empirical evidence in this regard is stil limited and requests further investigation, results suggest that these instruments are more important for adult learning than for others.41
Looking at the role funding instruments can play in relation to market failure and
funding barriers to participation, tax incentives address shared returns, because the state benefits from economic returns, e.g. tax revenues increase because of income returns to adult learning or decreasing dependence from welfare benefits. Therefore, tax incentives should be in place. (State subsidised) Loans address liquidity constraints and capital market imperfections as first best solution, while vouchers are suitable to overcome uncertainty of returns, i.e. the insecurity whether adult learning wil result in
39 Furthermore, a weakly significant correlation can also be identified between CVET-loans and LFS
2010 and LFS 2011participation rates in adult learning.
40 However, it is a bit surprising that non correlation could be found between and loans and participation
rates in formal, but for non-formal adult learning. The only correlation between loans and participation rates in formal adult learning , which is even only weakly significant, concerns LFS 2010 and 2011.
41 The findings are in line with previous qualitative research on tax incentives and vouchers, while no
relationship could be established for loans (PPMI/FiBS 2012). Furthermore, this study found that countries with lower participation rates address companies more than individuals, while countries with higher rates employ more funding instruments for individuals.
higher income or lower unemployment. Risk aversion is best addressed through flexible, income-contingent loans as well as 100% grants, which are – similar to supply-side funding – important if people are not willing or able to pay (much) for adult learning. Table 5 structures this approach and provides also an overview on second-best solutions, if first best instruments are not in place or implementable, e.g. because of political reasons.
Cost=sharing between
Reasons for under=investment in
state and individuals
adult learning and funding
instruments to overcome them
Shared returns betweenstate and individuals
Liquidity constraints
Capital market imperfections
Uncertainty of returns
Expcting low/no returns
No/limited willingness to pay
Equity/unequal access
X = first=best solution to overcome barrier(X) = first=best solution if certain conditions are met or complementary measures implemented to overcome barrier(x) = second=best solution to overcome barrier
Conditions/complementary measures1) state guarantees and/or interest subsidies2) income=contingent loans or human capital contracts3) if targeted at or preferential treatment for disadvantaged groups 4) state subsidies and/or interest subsidies5) paid training leave6) if upfront payment or in case that contribution of the individual is reduced due to transaction to provider7) if more than 100% of training costs can be deducted
Table 5: Taxonomy for financial intervention in adult learning financing
(Bi-variate) statistical analyses found significant results for capital market
imperfections and (almost) for uncertainty of returns, which could serve as first and preliminary indication that addressing these barriers may be more important than other fincancial barriers; particularly the latter is in line with previous research (PPMI/FiBS 2012). The former (capital market imperfections) would be in line with the role of loans, while insecurity could point to vouchers; however, these preliminary findings need further research, e.g. based on AES 2011.42
Although this study found only very limited relationships between funding and
participation rates at system's level, it is striking that decentral responsibility exists in al
42 The analyses in relation to AES 2011 conducted in this study should be considered preliminary as
data were not yet available for all countries; e.g. UK and Finland were missing at the time of analysis. UK data was added in mid-July 2013 only.
seven countries with highest participation rates according to AES/OECD-data (2007)43 11 out of 18 countries at the top employ this principle, while central responsibility prevails in the countries with low(er) participation rates. Statistical y (bi-variate), countries with higher total numbers of instruments show higher participation rates (LFS 2011), which could be an indication that decentral responsibility might be linked to higher participation rates.
Furthermore, the ful -country equivalent number of cost-sharing instruments shows
weakly significant correlations with overal (formal or non-formal) participation rates; and separately also with participation rates in non-formal adult learning, according to AES 2011. However, this should be taken with care.
Eventual y, reviewing the literature, empirical evidence on funding instruments and
their impact on adult learning is limited, if extremely high requirements are established
(Falch/Oosterbeek 2011; Oosterbeek 2013). However, it is even questionable, whether
such high requirements are real y appropriate for policy advice because they often only
confirm results from previous and more qualitative analyses and are only available after
years. For example, Dohmen (2007) estimated deadweight effects and mobilisation
effects of vouchers, based on literature review, to roughly 50% each, i.e. 50% of
participants would have participated even without the voucher, while the remaining half
would have not. Both studies mentioned (Falch/Oosterbeek 2011; Oosterbeek 2013)
arrive, based on a very smal number of examples and with a strong focus on a Swiss
example (it should be noted, though, that CH is very unique as turned out during
previous analyses of this study!) at a deadweight loss of about 60%. Even that better
educated people are more likely to make use of vouchers – as is the case for al non-
restricted (targeted) funding instruments – while low qualified participate
disproporationately less, is envisable from previous (more) qualitative research, e.g.
based on evaluation studies, even if they do not employ such rigorous methods.
Research on vouchers has shown this from the early beginning for al education
sectors (Dohmen/Fuchs 2007; Dohmen 2007, 2010).
A core problem of vouchers is that disadvantaged, particularly low-qualified groups
have difficulties to make use of them, but even more with taking quality-oriented decisions based on information (Kruppe 2006, 2008; and Dohmen/Fuchs 2007; Dohmen 2010; Dohmen/Ramirez-Rodriguez 2010 for overviews on research). This core problem needs further research and wel -defined action in order to increase participation of these groups in adult learning. With regard to such under-represented groups they need to be targeted through more systematic and overarching approaches, combating several, if not even al relevant barriers at the same time (FiBS/Research
43 In order to include comparable statistical information on participation in adult learning for the non-
European countries this study relied on AES 2007 and OECD 2012-data. In a previous study on behalf of Cedefop (PPMI/FiBS 2012), we were able to identify statistical patterns based on LFS-data. For a critical review of the LFS-data in general, but in particular with regard to its role as European benchmark indicator see Oosterbeek (2013).
voor Beleid 2012). It is likely that pro-active methods to approach these target groups are advisable, instead of ‘waiting that they come'.
Although almost al European countries employ training leave regulations, their
impact on participation rates is rather smal ; take up is rarely above 1% level – however, exeptions exist (SE: 6.2%; PT: 4.4%; BE: 1.7%; LV: 1.4%; UK: 1.4% (Cedefop 2012a; PPMI/FiBS 2012).
Empirical evidence on the effectiveness of tax incentives is also limited, only few
studies are available (Cedefop 2009; Leuven/Oosterbeek 2004), suggesting that they may have a very smal , though relatively substantial positive impact on take-up of learning. However, as with vouchers, deadweight loss is around 50%.44 Yet, it appears that outreach of tax incentives is sometimes quite high in comparison to other instruments. For example, 400.000 people are said to have deducted training expenses from the tax base in Germany (Cedefop 2009). However, similar to the other instruments, data on take-up is rather limited.
Regulations on payback clauses exist in most European countries, either
established at national, social partner or company level, intending to safeguard employer's investment in learning in case the employ resigns the employment contract shortly after training (Cedefop 2012b). Despite its broad existence it appears that payback clauses become only very rarely effective, in the sense that employees have to repay costs of learning. One reason may be that employee only rarely quit contracts shortly after training, another that reimbursement would be rather limited, e.g. because of the commonly limited costs of training.
Saving schemes hardly exist in Europe; the only scheme, actual y operating, is the
Austrian schemes, which, in fact, is a combined savings and loan scheme. Yet, take-up is extremely limited, particularly in relation to adult learning, even though individuals are entitled to a low-interest loan, issued immediately after signing the contract.45 The very limited relevance of saving schemes seems due to systematic reasons: (1) costs of adult learning are commonly fairly smal , (2) savings are particularly important for low income earners who are usual y not in a position to save especial y for education, as their liquidity is rather constrained, (3) it is questionable, whether savings for education are economical y rationale, because it affects the liquidity for other consumption or investment purposes. If such a liquidity constraint would result in another credit, taken
44 Strikingly, Oosterbeek (2013) argues on the one hand that tax incentives are an effective instrument,
while he considers vouchers rather ineffective, although the deadweight effect of tax incentives is roughly 50%, while that of vouchers is around 60%. It is hardly plausible that this 10%-difference marks the borderline between effective and ineffective instruments. In contrast, based on the results of this study it seems hardly possible, at least in practice, to design funding instruments without any or with very small deadweight effects. Furthermore, it is very likely that any trial will result in substantial administrative burden, which would than be criticised because of its limited effectiveness.
45 Another saving schemes established in the Netherlands has been disclosed because of its low take-
up; the German saving scheme, which is part of the education premia, is not real y a saving schemes, despite its name. In contrast, it enables individuals to withdraw funds from a state supported saving scheme for learning purposes during the seven years grace period, without losing state subsidy.
up for example, to buy a new car (or whatever), the interest rate for the credit would be higher than the interest return to educational savings, resulting in a loss, (4) savings plans for training are also unattractive for commercial banks, because the smal amounts and low relevance of larger amounts saved result in relatively high costs (Dohmen 1999, 2007).
An overall problem to judge the effectiveness of funding instruments is data
availability; take-up figures are only available for few funding instruments; the overal
impression is, though, that take-up rates are commonly rather smal . Even
comparatively large schemes, in the sense of broad eligibility criteria, such as, for
example, the training cheque NRW, reach not more than 5 or 6% of eligible population
(Dohmen 2013); altogether take-up rates of national and regional schemes in almost al
German states add up to utmost 140 or 150,000 per year, which is approximately 5%
of adults spending own money for adult learning. Another example are the regional
vouchers in Austria, for which Dohmen (2009) estimated an overal take-up of
approximately 100,000, or the vouchers from the Chambers of Labour, available to al
employees in Austria. Whether the funding schemes in the Nordic countries are real y
more successful is unknown, due to lack of data; however, it appears as such (almost)
universal schemes may contribute to higher participation rates; we wil come back to
this issue below.
Take-up figures of the use of various funding instruments at national level are even
more limited. Data available for Norway suggest that 25% of al adults participate in publicly funded learning (estimation based on statistics from the Norwegian expert provided for this study). In Germany, tax incentives are likely to be most important, with 400.000 beneficiaries (2004) (Cedefop 2009), 166,000 through master craftsmen grants and loans (Statistisches Bundesamt/Federal Office of Statistics 2012), and up to 150,000 via various voucher and grant schemes (Dohmen 2013a, 2013b), while those enrol ed in second chance education are not included in these figures. However, these figures are indicative and likely underreporting total take-up of available funding opportunities.46 The limited availability of data on take-up rates and funding volumes cal s on the one hand for national level activities; on the other hand it might also cal for action at EU level.
Another advice is to employ funding instruments addressing individuals directly to
them and not via employers, because companies fol ow necessarily another logic than catering for disadvantaged groups. In contrast, companies support commonly the better-off more than under-represented groups.
Overal , the previous analysis suggests that public funding should be
complementary to individual and company funding; i.e. high income individuals are very likely to participate in adult learning independently from public incentives; the same applies to companies, often caring also for better-educated (and better paid)
46 For this very reason, section 4 did not contain any indicator on spending per beneficiary.
employees, while staff with low(er) qualifications is less supported. Since the latter group is often neither wil ing nor able to pay for training, but are highly rewarding to the public, they should be at the core of public and political attention.
The fol owing table summarises the strengths and weaknesses of the various
funding instruments:
Strengths
Weakness
instrument
100% grants
Allow easy and wel -defined
Huge deadweight effect, if poorly
Do not require co-funding (from
Administrative burden high (if targeted)
under-represented groups)
Application procedure often complicated
No (financial) entry barrier
Require active application of individuals, may turn out as additional barrier
Fee reduction/ Reduced/limited cost burden for
Huge deadweight effect, if poorly
exemption
Do not require co-funding (from
Require administration to control
target groups), in case of fee
Low or even no (financial) entry barrier
Supply-side
Reduces cost burden for target
Huge deadweight effect, if poorly
Does not require co-funding
Utilisation/take-up difficult to control
Low or no entry barrier (depending on whether co-funding is required or not)
(Cost-sharing) Cost-sharing responds to shared
Take-up rate of underrepresented
vouchers
groups usually low
Allow easy and wel defined
Co-financing requirement may prevent
participation (of low income or under-represented groups)
Can respond flexible to different environments
Deadweight effect high, unless targeted at underrepresented groups
Administrative burden high (if targeted)
Application procedure often complicated
Require active application of individuals, may turn out as additional barrier
Supply may be very limited in areas with low population density or for learners with special needs, because programs cannot be run economical y, unless complementary measures taken (e.g. adjusted voucher values etc.)
Training leave Time constraint can be overcome
Costly from the viewpoint of the
(paid and
employer (paid leave)
Paid TL does help to cover costs
of living and/or costs of learning
Participation depends upon employer agreement
Does not increase funding for AL
Allow cost-sharing for costly
Pre-financing requirement; liquidity
incentives
constraint not resolved
Easy to administer/limited
Cost recovery (public co-financing)
administrative burden
increases with income;
Are, in fact, often not restricted to
No or very limited incentive for low
fees, but cover also other costs,
e.g. travel, accommodation, learning materials etc.
Enable financing of costly AL
Take-up of risk-averse groups limited
Costs of living and other costs
Adverse selection in case of market
solution with public guarantees
Administration costs likely to be high, contributing to high interest surcharges
State subsidy not visible because hidden in lower interest rates
Interest rates may be higher than for savings, disadvantaging loan takers (often from disadvantaged groups)
Allow saving of huge amounts
Saving of higher amounts requires long-
term anticipation of AL needs/plans
High administration costs
Interest rates/returns are commonly low
Banks/financial service companies are not interested (unless costs are covered by individuals via lower interest rates or by state subsidies)
Table 6: Strengths and weaknesses of funding instruments
6. Financing of certain target groups and learning providers
This section reviews funding for three different target groups – second chance
education/provision of basic skil s, higher education (for the first time) later in life, and older/retired people – and for learning providers.
6.1 Second chance education/basic skills provision
73 mil ion Europeans have not graduated from upper secondary education and
would be in need of additional qualifications to possess the minimum qualification for a successful employment; people with utmost lower secondary education are considered as low-qualified.47 Therefore, the European Union puts much emphasis on reducing early school leaving and gaining additional qualifications and competences. Reviewing participation rates of low-qualified in adult learning reveals that they participate much less than better qualified. However, it needs to be taken into consideration that the group of low-qualified consists of several sub-groups, where often various hampering factors are combined; for example, age, migration background and health problems etc. The share of low-qualified increases with age, i.e. large shares of low qualified in each country are older people; and the share of low-qualified is much higher among females, particularly in older cohorts.
From a micro as wel as macro-economic perspective, investment in second chance
education/basic skil provision (SCE/BSP) pays off in most countries (see Figure 13), though rates of return to second chance education are lower than for initial secondary education. Investment in SCE is substantial in most countries and it appears that countries investing more in SCE/BSP benefit through decreasing rates of low qualified adults.
In spite of these positive returns and the substantial amounts invested, it appears
that numbers and shares of participants in SCE are relatively modest (see Table 7). Apart from HU (take-up rate48 12%), CAN (7%) and USA (7%), figures are rather smal . For example, the share seems to be rather low in AT (0.4%), CH (0.4%) and NL (close to 0%).49 The discrepancy between substantial investment and participation rates is seemingly due to high unit costs on the one hand and limited interest from individuals, which is, strikingly enough, obviously even economical y rationale in many cases, although they do not have to contribute own means commonly.
47 In contrast, the term low-skil ed refers to functional aspects and is more subjective. For example, a
person with a university degree is commonly not considered low qualified, but may be considered low-skilled, e.g. because of long absence from the labour market.
48 The take-up rate defines the share of beneficiaries in relation to the total target population, here the
49 Under-reporting cannot be excluded.
Private and public internal rates of return to upper secondary education at age 40
(ranked according to male public rates of return)
France Denm itzerland Spain Germ
Zealand Poland
Czech Republic Canada Belgium Ireland
United Kingdom Hungary
United States Portugal
male private rates
female private rates
male public rates
female public rates
Source: OECD EAG 2008
Figure 13: Private and public rates of return to upper secondary education at age 40 (ranked
according to public rates of return for male)
Participation rates of low qualified correlate negatively with the share of low qualified
in a country and are highest (see Figure 14) in countries where rates of return are lowest, e.g. in DK, FI and NO. In contrast, participation rates are sometimes low in countries with high private and/or public returns. However, some exceptions exist: HU and, particularly the USA and PT show high returns and relatively high participation rates, either with regard to SCE/BSP or to adult learning in general. The core explanatory factor for high or low rates of return from the individual perspective is the unemployment rate, i.e. rates of return are lower in countries, where unemployment rates are lower. When regarding differences in rates of return by gender, rates of return are higher for the sex, for which the unemployment rate is lower. From a public perspective, the difference between unemployment benefits and fiscal returns matters. Furthermore, it should be noted that the unemployment rate shows links not only to private and public rates of return, but also to participation in adult learning of individuals (of al education levels). Statistical analyses carried out in the context of this study suggest a negative relationship between the long-term unemployment rate and LFS participation in adult learning, even when accounting for differences in economic performance between countries. This means that participation in adult learning appears to be higher in countries where unemployment rates are lower. Females, in contrast to males, are found to be more (less) prone to participate in adult learning if they are employed (unemployed).
2012 2010 2010 2008 2010 2010 2011 2011 2010 2010 2011
basic skil s budget / participant
(in € 1,000) B) Participants
upgrade attainment
level budget / participant
(in € 1,000) A+B) total
participants SCE
SCE average total
(budget / particpant) Take-up rate (parti-
4.1% 0.1% 12.2% 0.0%
cipants/ target grp)
Table 7: Take-up rates and average budget spend per participant on second chance education
and basic skil provision to for low-qualified (numbers x 1,000, budget in € 1,00050).
Participation rates of low=qualified in adult learning (AES 2007 and 2011)
Source: AES 2007 and 2011
Figure 14: Participation of low qualified in adult learning 2007 and 2011.
50 Budgets are not corrected for purchasing power parities.
From a mere economic perspective, these findings suggest to apply more focussed
policies and to invest in SCE/BSP only, if private and/or public returns are high enough to justify this investment. Even though this would, of course, suggest to employ SCE/BSP policies particularly for younger people and in cases where unemployment rates of low qualified are higher and lower for medium qualified, even second chance education for people around aged 40 pays-off in certain countries.
In many countries, funding is completely through the public purse, either applying
(conditional or unconditional) supply-side funding or 100% grants; individuals themselves have to contribute own means only very rarely, and if they have to pay, the amounts are commonly rather smal . Another question is, whether funding concerns only fees or the costs of learning providers or whether funding for costs of living is available; the latter is commonly the case for the unemployed, though not necessarily for others. However, an interesting finding from AES 2011 is that the mean hours of formal adult learning appears to be rather limited, though, varying across countries from 15 hours in Luxembourg to 59 in Germany. Furthermore, values decreased in many countries between 2007 and 2011.
Obstacles to participation in lifelong learning:
Training was too expensive or respondent could not afford it (AES 2011) in %, by educational level
Pre=primary, primary and lower secondary education (levels 0=2) 2011Upper secondary and post=secondary non=tertiary education (levels 3 and 4) 2011First and second stage of tertiary education (levels 5 and 6) 2011
Figure 15: Obstacle – Training was too expensive or respondent could not afford it (AES 2011)
in %, by educational level (ranked according to share of low-qualified mentioning
costs/affordability as obstacle)
The most important finding concerning funding is that take-up figures appear to be
low even in countries with publicly financed entitlements, as e.g. in Norway, which suggests that additional measures are necessary to overcome various, if not even all,
barriers at the same time. It seems even likely that funding is not at the core at al in many countries.
However, the previous finding that low-qualified have to contribute only very little, if
at al , stands in some contrast to Figure 15 above, which reviews the reason ‘costs too high/unaffordable' as cause for non-participation by education attainment. The EU 27 average in the AES 2011 survey shows only slight differences between the different educational levels, by and large. However, the look at country-related data shows three different groups of countries: In several countries across al regions low qualified perceive costs more as a barrier than medium and highly qualified. Among these countries are FR, NL, AT and CH as Western European countries, CZ, HU, EE and particularly RO as newer member states. Romania is outstanding, because more than two thirds of non-participating low qualified argue with costs, whereas only one third of highly qualified mentions this reason. Comparatively smal are the higher shares of low qualified in Norway, in CY and in IT.
This finding suggests that public funding is obviously not available to al (low
qualified) adults, but that a certain and varying share is either not aware of the funding opportunitiy or not addressed through funding schemes. For example, while unemployed people in Germany are addressed through the employment agency they are not (or only very rarely) targeted through other funding instruments, i.e. the federal training premia or state-level instruments. It seems likely that this is also the case in other countries, preventing relevant groups of society from participation in adult learning.51
From a European perspective, this cal s for differentiated policies, supporting
especial y policies to the advantage of low qualified on the one hand in countries where costs or funding are more of a problem than for other groups and countries. On the other hand, additional barriers need to be surmounted in those countries where funding is not at the core, i.e. in those countries where funding is (almost) no barrier for low qualified.
6.2 Higher education (for the first time) later in life
An important finding with regard to higher education later in life is that public and
private internal rates of return are substantial (see Figure 16) and sometimes even higher than for initial tertiary education, though important differences across countries and by gender exist. Although higher education later in life pays-off in many countries, it does not pay-off in any country; particularly the Nordic countries show very low rates.
51 A re-analysis of the German AES 2010 suggests that a substantial share of people not in employment
points to "funding/affordability" as a barrier, suggesting that funding modalities are either insufficient for this target group or that knowledge about funding opportunities is limited. In fact, it appears that funding for this group is hardly available, despite funding from the employment agency.
Private and public internal rates of return to higher education at age 40
Female private IRR
Female public IRR
Source: OECD EAG 2008
Figure 16: Private and public Internal Rates of Higher Education later in life for male and female
(ranked alphabetical y).
The fol owing Figure 17, ranked by the share of students aged 40+, reviews the
share of mature students in relation to al tertiary education students. It highlights substantial differences in the share of tertiary education students aged 30 years and above across the OECD-countries, ranging from 3% in Greece to 33% in Sweden and Norway. Looking at the whole group of mature students, the 24 countries can be grouped into four clusters with six countries each and with relatively clear demarcation lines. At the top are al four Northern European countries and UK and AU; while SE and NO are above 30%, Finland and Denmark are close to 30%, with the UK almost at the same level than Finland. Australia fal s slightly behind. Al six countries have a share of mature students of wel above 25%. A second group comprises six countries clearly above the 20% level, i.e. AT, US, CH, PT, LU and ES. The third group has rates above 15%, covering SK, IE, HU, CZ and CA, Germany is close to the 15% rate, but fal s clearly short of the levels of the other groups, but is also wel above BE, NL and KR.
Focussing the age group 40+, the picture becomes slightly more divers. SE, NO and
UK remain clearly at the top with 15%, while AU, FI, DK and the US are also above 10% but wel below the countries at the top. The remaining countries show rates of wel below 10%, headed by AT, PT and IE and fol owed by CH, CA and ES.
It seems possible and appropriate to cluster the 24 countries into three groups.
Some countries are clearly ahead of others, SE and NO are in the highest ranges in both groups, while DK, FI, AU and UK as well as CH and AT are in the top group for one age cohort and in the upper medium in the other. The first four countries show comparatively higher rates in the older, the latter two in the younger cohort.
A second group of countries rankes in the middle, with upper medium to high shares
of 30 to 39 year olds in tertiary education, and varying clusters for those aged 40+. This group comprises several Western (IE, DE), Southern (ES, PT, IT), newer member states (CZ, HU, SK) and CA as non-European country. The remaining five countries show comparatively low rates in both age cohorts; this is valid for FR and particularly for EL, KR, NL and BE.
Share of mature tertiary education students by age group
12% 13% 14% 14% 11%
Source: own calculations based on OECD=data
Figure 17: Share of mature tertiary education students by age group (2010) (ranked by share of
students aged 40+).
Looking at the funding policies employed in the three clusters the link between
funding modalities and the shares of mature or non-traditional students becomes obvious, The first group employs open access policies, providing funds to people entering the HE system without almost any age restriction (up to age 60). Not surprisingly, this policy is linked to comparatively high participation rates of mature students in HE, as can be observed for the Anglo-american and the Nordic countries. Furthermore, when looking at the details, e.g. the application or non-application of means-testing either for loans and/or grants, some smal er differences may be attributed to this. While the Nordic countries do not employ any means-testing, which is also the case for the loan schemes in the UK (England) and Australia, the USA employs means-testing to grants and (interest-subsidised) loans. While the former countries have often higher rates of mature students, the share are slightly lower in the UK (England) and Australia, and are another bit lower in the USA. Thus, while it appears that the existence of funding instruments as such is more important than the special type of instrument, i.e. loans are obviously wel accepted to finance HE later in life, which may be due to the fact that most of this age cohort gained experience in
taking-up loans and may also be supported indirectly through repayment conditions. In contrast, means-testing seems to make a difference, though.
A second group of countries, applying either general funding regulations with age
restrictions wel beyond the common age levels of initial higher education, i.e. above age 30 and, for example, up to age 40 or 45, or established special regulations providing funds under certain conditions. Countries belonging to the first sub-group are, for example, DE and HU, though at least in the case of DE this has not yet lead to high(er) participation rates, despite several attention over the last couple of years.52 AT is an example for countries belonging to the second sub-group, because some funding is available to support successful graduation for universities studies. Furthermore, it seems that a higher education policy supporting only a limited share of students in initial higher education with ful -cost grants, while the rest has to pay ful -cost fees, results in comparatively high participation rates of mature students. This group is likely to comprise largely students, who are not from better-off families, which would have been able to pay ful -cost fees at age 20, when enrolment in initial education usual y takes place.
A third group of countries emphasises only initial higher education; in such countries
funding is restricted to age 30, if not even less, and support is commonly dependent on parental income; often some support is even targeted at parents. As a result, shares of mature students are very limited.
Eventual y, it is important to understand that funding policies alone are not enough
to support lifelong learning in HE, but that additional policies and measure are required (see the report for Lot 3 "Opening higher education to adults" in this regard).
6.3 Learning of older and retired people
As is the case for low qualified, also older (aged 55 to 64) and particularly retired
people participate less in adult learning; often low qualification levels and age are correlated, since the share of low qualified is much higher for older age cohorts. As already mentioned this is even more pronounced for females.
Figure 18 reveals that participation rates of older people increase between 2007 and
2011 in most European countries, and particularly for CH, DK, and FR, while decreasing rates can be observed in NO, CZ, SK, LT, LV, and EL. Of these countries, NO and EL are outstanding, NO because of its high participation rate despite reduction, and EL because of its extremely low rate. However, this increase in participation rates goes along with decreasing rates of older people in formal education, which even halved in some countries, such as Belgium, or vanished in others, such as DE and IT. Although disparity between younger and older age cohorts decreased, i.e. the increase
52 Policy with regard to the target group changed only very recently. The student support scheme has
only been enhanced in late 2010, while data in Figure 17 concerns also the year 2010, the KfW study loan raised age limited to age 44 at the beginning of 2013.
in participation rates of older is higher than for younger cohorts (or decrease is lower), disparity has even increased in some countries. Eventual y, mean time of instruction for older people is (even) lower than for al participants.
When reviewing the participation rate of older people by various sub-categories (see
Figure 19), it turns out that one third of those employed are active adult learners, while less than 10% of already retired people are active, suggesting that employment status matters. Thus, this study identifies not age itself but employment status as core explanatory variable for participation rates, re-confirming previous analyses (OECD 2004; Hansson 2008; Bassanini et al. 2006). Furthemore, employment status of older people itself is linked to two different aspects, educational attainment and retirement policies. The share of employed people, aged 55 and above is higher the higher educational attainment in this age group and vice versa, i.e. the share of low qualified in employment is much lower, while the share of unemployed or inactive low-qualified is much higher. Low-qualified retire earlier, e.g. because of physical y demanding jobs etc. Furthemore, the three variables (educational attainment, adult learning and (early) retirement) are often interlinked, i.e. those with higher education remain longer in employment and participate more in adult learning. However, this is not valid in any case, some countries have a high effective retirement age, sometimes even higher than official retirement age, but participation rates remain limited.
Participation of age group 55A64 in adult learning (AES 2007, 2011)
Lithuania M Belgium Latvia
Czech RepublicHungaryPortugalSlovakia ItalySlovenia Spain EU 27CyprusEstonia FranceAustria
Figure 18: EU27 - Participation rate in formal and non-formal education and training in different
age groups in %. (ranking according to AES 2011)
Overal , when regarding the statistical relationship between participation in adult
learning and educational attainment for adults aged 55 to 64, a positive relationship is
suggested for the share of (older) adults with tertiary education (ISCED levels 5 and 6) and participation (AES/OECD 2007 as wel as LFS), even after accounting for differences in economic performances between countries. Consequently, countries with higher shares of high qualified older adults are also those with higher participation rates of this age group in adult learning. The opposite holds when regarding the AES/OECD 2007 participation of the same age group of adults, yet with a low primary education level. Here a significant negative relationship is observed, even when control ing for GDP per capita. This confirms that participation in adult learning is lower in countries with high shares of low-qualified older people.
Participation in non=formal education and training in the last 12 months in different
groups, sample: only people aged 55 to 64
Fulfilling domestic tasks
Permanently disabled
In retirement or early retirement or has given up business
Other inactive person
Pupil, student, further training, unpaid work experience
Carries out a job or profession, including unpaid work for a
family business or holding, including an apprenticeship or paid
traineeship, etc.
Figure 19: Participation in non-formal education and training in the last 12 months in different
groups, sample: only people aged 55 to 64. Source: Calculation by the authors with data from
Going one step further, and differentiating the share of adults aged 55 to 74 by
educational status and employment status, multivariate analysis (control ing for GDP per capita) suggests that the previously elaborated relationships between AES/OECD 2007 participation and the share of old(er) adults with primary and tertiary education levels hold irrespective of the employment status (employed or unemployed) and are of similar strength. However, one must note that nearly significant results, if e.g. LFS participation rates are instead used for estimation, point out that employment status may matter in this respect. Overal , these results are in line with previous observations and portray that age itself is not the core explanatory factor in relation to participation in
adult learning, but educational attainment, whereas the role of employment status needs further investigation, though results suggest that it may matter, i.e. the more older people are „stil " in employment the higher the participation rate.
Lastly, both the effective retirement ages of men and women show a positive
relationship with LFS participation in adult learning, after control ing for GDP per capita. This suggests that participation in adult learning is higher in countries in which adults work for a longer period of their life, i.e. increasing effective retirement age is, thus, likely to increase participation rates of older people in adult learning.
Retired people participate even less and particularly for different, non-job related
factors become more pronounced. Many countries address this group through various supply-side driven activities, such as "universities of the 3rd age", senior study programme in higher education or specific provision of learning opportunities at community level. These activities are not linked to any additional and specific funding opportunities, apart from covering the costs of provision of learning opportunities and/or cross-subsidisation. However, the USA has some minor programmes for this target group; in CZ the university of the third age is a voucher programme for older people. Furthermore, some programmes implicitly address this group of retired people, either because they are not restricted to any age limit or because they target people above a certain age threshold without restricting funding to employment status.
Relationship between employment rate of older people (LFS 2010) and participation in adult learning
(AES 2011)
5
5
d
e
g
a 50
le
p
o
e
f p 40
o
te
ra
n 30
rticip 20
Employment rate of people aged 55A60
Figure 20: Relationship between employment rate of people aged 55-64 and their AES 2011
participation rate.
Eventual y, it is worth to mention that funding is less of an obstacle than for younger
age cohorts, while are dispositional barriers (e.g. health status) become more
important. Not surprisingly, the reason "do not need it for the job" is more pronounced (see Figure 21).
In general, and similar to the finding in the previous section on higher education later
in life and in spite of the limited role of funding as an obstacle, it appears that participation rates are higher in countries employing open access funding policies, as the Nordic countries do in particular and the Anglo-american countries to some extent. Such open funding opportunities address (almost) the whole population and are often embedded in practised lifelong learning cultures and policies (see also below). Other countries, basical y those with participation rates around the (European) average employ targeted funding schemes for (certain groups of) older people, though employing varying definitions of older people (addressing either the age cohort 45+, 50+ or even 55+). However, the very few schemes for which take-up data is available, e.g. in the German states of Hesse and Rhineland-Palatinate, suggest that the number of beneficiaries is rather limited. The remaining countries with low or limited participation rates of older people employ either more project-based funding policies, e.g. through tenders, or have commonly very little funding opportunities for adult learning available, if any.
Obstacles why respondents did not want to participate in education and training by age,
participants: Respondents, who did not participate but wanted to participate 2011
No access to a computer or internet (for distance learning)
Respondent experienced difficulties in finding what he/she wanted
There was no training offered at the reachable distance
Respondent did not have time because of family responsibilities
Training conflicted with work schedule
Lack of employer's support or public services support
Training was too expensive or respondent could not afford it
Respondent did not have the prerequisites
Respondent did not need it for personal (non job related) reasons
Respondent did not need it for the job
From 55 to 64 years
Source: Eurostat 2013
Figure 21: Obstacles why respondents did not want to participate in education and training by
age, participants: Respondents, who did not participate but wanted to participate 2011.
Yet, in the future it is highly likely that participation rates of older people wil
increase, as can be seen for the period 2007 to 2011in most European countries (see Figure 18).
6.4 Funding situation of learning provider
The structure of learning providers is very heterogeneous in the European countries,
though certain types are prevalent across al countries, by and large (AES 2007). Across al countries, learning institutions from employers form the biggest group with almost 40% on average, and up to almost 70% in BG. In contrast, the share of employers as learning providers seems almost non-existant in Hungary. The second largest group are "institutions for non-formal education/further education" (16.5%), fol owed by "institutions for formal education/further education" (10%) and business institutions (9%). Around 5%, each, are "chambers of commerce", non-commercial institutions, individuals, and non-profit-associations. However, the role the various types of learning providers play in each single country varies a lot.
Overal , available research on learning providers and their financing is stil rather
limited, particularly in a cross-country perspective. Therefore, and in order to close this gap at least to some extent, this study conducted an (experimental) online-survey in seven countries (Austria, Germany, Hungary, Italy, Netherlands, Slovakia, and Slovenia). More than 400 learning providers, out of more than 3,000 invited, took part in this survey, showing a very diverse picture.53
Fees from participants are of particular importance to learning providers in
Germany54, Austria, and, though with some differences, of medium importance for the Netherlands and Slovenia while fees from employers play a major role for learning providers in HU and SI. In contrast, fees from employers are almost irrelevant for German providers, responding to the survey. In contrast, public grants are of major importance for learning providers in Germany and Italy; furthermore, grants from background institution/financier/sponsoring body are extremely important in Germany.
Reviewing to what extent learning providers are affected by the crisis, i.e. in
particular hit by cuts in their sources of funding, learning providers in HU and IT were (strongly or slightly) affected from shrinking fees from participants; for HU this applies even more for fees from companies. In contrast, German and Austrian providers are affected only to a minor extent. The only country where a vast majority of learning providers state that they were affected from cuts in public budgets is Italy; whereas this applies to almost half of the Hungarian providers, which are also more affected from cuts in sponsoring than learning providers in other countries.
Furthermore, private-for-profit providers are far more dependent on fees from
participants or companies and are, thus, far more affected by the crisis. In contrast,
53 As response to the invitation to participate in the survey was voluntarily and not al provider addresses
were available, but in some countries even selective by nature, it is likely that results are biased. The following information should, thus, be seen in the light of this remark.
The questionnaires (see section 0 in the annex) as well as the invitation letters were translated into
national languages.
54 Folk high schools are over-represented in the German sample, though it seems likely that fees would
play an even more pronounced role if selection of learning providers would be more in line with overall distribution of learning providers in Germany.
only up to one third of public providers mention reductions in funding sources, whether from private or from public sources as a problem; except for funding from employment agencies in Germany. Funding is perceived far more of a problem in Hungary and Slovenia than in the other countries.
Overal , these findings clearly indicate that learning providers in some countries are
far more affected from the crisis than in others. Furthermore, it appears that cuts in public budgets are far more of a problem for learning providers in Italy and Hungary than in Germany and particularly Austria and Slovenia. Learning providers in Hungary suffered also far more from shrinking fee revenues from participants and companies, whichis though to a lesser extent, also the case for IT, SK and SI.
In order to review the chal enges learning providers face and how they are affected
by changing funding environments, a regular learning provider business climate index at European level could be established, fol owing the German Ifo-business climate index, which has been translated in a national learning provider index. This index shows that learning providers in Germany were more or less affected from changing requirements and funding opportunities during the crisis; some learning providers benefited temporarily a lot from additional public funding provided for employers and helping them to surmount the crisis by substituting short-term work arrangements by learning opportunities for their employees, while those learning providers depend mainly on employer funding experience business cycles fol owing the common pattern, experiencing sharp cuts during the crisis.
7. Conclusions and recommendations
One of the core conclusions of this study is that adult learning pays-off and that
returns to adult learning are substantial and accrue to individuals, employers and society at the same time, suggesting a cost-sharing between al three or even four stakeholders, if employment agencies exist in a country. Furthermore, several adult learning indicators show stronger correlations with innovation performance than higher education; and countries with higher growth rates during the last five years show higher participation rates in adult learning – however, the identification of causalities needs further research, although the fact that the correlation is stronger for the time-lag model than for a model without time-lag may suggest that adult learning has a positive effect on mid-term growth. Relationships to AES 2011 participation are stronger than for AES 2007.
Reviewing funding volumes and distribution, countries with higher participation rates
show higher funding amounts in general, but also in relation to various indicators, e.g. spending per adult or spending per adult and per hour. Although funding from employers and states seem to be drivers of adult learning participation, statistical analysis confirms this only for state funding, while contribution from individuals is significantly – and for several indicators – negatively correlated with adult learning participation, even if control ed for GDP as core explanatory factor. This finding has two
implications: First of al , costs for the individual should be kept low (or even reduced), if participation rates are to be increased. Secondly, increasing participation rates through public funding policies is linked to increasing deadweight effects, if funding is not targeted at those in need of funding, and who otherwise wil not participate; however, since funding is neither the only nor the most important barrier, this should be complemented by accompanying measures addressing other barriers, which vary a lot between individuals, though.
This suggests developing comprehensive lifelong learning strategies and cultures,
which are obviously a major component in order to reach higher participation rates. Countries with high participation rates in general, but also with regard to certain target groups, e.g. low qualified, mature/non-traditional students or older people, employ open access policies, in the sense that (public) funding is available to (almost) al adults, and often through a rather smal number of instruments. However, as regards effectiveness it is likely that high deadweight effects persist, as highly educated people are likely to enrol in adult education even without public funding.
In contrast, countries with low participation rates are stil very much, if not even
almost exclusively oriented towards initial education. Funding for adult learning is very limited and often tender- or project-based, and, thus, not aiming at establishing sustainable structures. In between the two clusters are countries which commenced their way towards a comprehensive lifelong learning strategy and culture; these countries employ often various instruments for several target groups, demanding participants to search for information about funding sources. Because search and utilisation of information is linked to initial education, this advantageous better and disadvantages less educated people.
Furthermore, it seems that the latter group is strongly oriented towards funding for
unemployed and companies, while funding for other groups is (almost) non existent. Previous research (PPMI/FiBS 2012) suggests that countries with higher participation rates address individuals rather than companies, i.e. the number of funding instruments for individuals is higher, the number of instruments for companies is higher in countries with low(er) participation rates. This suggests to re-orientate funding towards individuals and to provide (more) funding opportunities for under-represented groups, even if they are in employment.
With regard to older people, education levels and a higher effective retirement age
are important drivers for participation in adult learning for this group; i.e. rising retirement age could be a short-term policy in order to increase their participation rates. Funding itself – as wel as time constraints because of family or job – is less of a problem for this group than health, age and limited learning needs because of job, i.e. accompanying measures are probably more at the core than funding. This applies also to second chance education, where most countries employ ful -cost funding or request only a smal funding part from the individual. In spite of this comparatively comfortable
situation, participant figures appear stil limited, although funding in many countries is substantial.
Another suggestion resulting from this study concerns European indicators: (1) The
trade-off between increasing participation rates according to AES and decreasing mean hours of instruction suggest to establish an indicator which combines both factors, e.g. multiplying the share of adults participating in adult learning with the average hours of instruction. This indicator would also respond to the varying role and duration of formal and non-formal learning. (2) The correlation between adult learning and innovation output (performance), which seems to be even stronger than the role of (initial) higher education, should be recognised in the Innovation Union Scoreboard.
Eventual y, even though concerns about data limitations are mentioned in almost
every study, unfortunately, it needs to be mentioned that data limitations are a serious problem with regard to adult learning, hampering research and policy advice. Apart from participation rates, for which the adult education survey 2011 seems to provide a very good picture by and large, al other data are incomplete, not to say even sketchy, and commonly hardly comparable. Even at national level this is a matter of concern, particularly as far as funding volumes are concerned, which are either incomplete or available for certain (one) year(s) only. Different national understandings and definitions of adult learning are another issue hampering comparability of national data.
Annex: Country-specific considerations
The fol owing section provides a brief overview on some core aspects and concern
on a country by country basis.
Australia applies very general and overarching funding policies with regard to its
adult population, no distinction is made between initial and continuing VET and no age restrictions apply to its funding instruments, as far as we could establish. It might therefore not be surprising that Australia has comparatively high participation rates when people aged 40+ are concerned, with the vast majority of almost 10% in VET, while only 1% of this age cohort is enrol ed in higher education. With regard to non-vocational adult learning, it should be noted that this topic is obviously not recognised as public responsibility. Thus, the fol owing refers to vocational adult learning.
According to our data over 80% of funds for the VET system are provided by the
eight state and territory governments to public and private providers (known as Registered Training Organisations RTOs) . For an individual student in a government supported place the government funding is over 90% of the cost of tuition. Funding comprises conditional, demand-led financing of learning providers as well as grant and loan support for individuals.
The key instruments for VET are entitlements for al persons of working age to a
(state or territory) government subsidised place at least for a first Certificate III. In addition, VET fees are quite low compared with university fees. In New South Wales
where there is a specified state level system of charges for VET the higher annual fee is $1,720 for an Advanced Diploma and as low as $506 for a Certificate I or II. For students from low income/disadvantaged background the government subsidy is considerably higher than for other students. The fee such students are charged is usual y called a concession fee and is as low as $100 per annum in the state New South Wales for 2013. Around twenty per cent of al VET students are eligible for the concession rate. Furthermore, financial assistance is available to about 15% of students in ful time VET. Eventual y, an income contingent loan is provided by the Australian government and is available to students taking Diploma and Advanced Diploma courses. This is cal ed VET FEE-HELP and is very similar to HECS HELP. This is a new development except in Victoria where it has been available for two years. So far the take up rate by students is relatively low compared with university students. The reasons for this include the complexity of the elements of VET courses and also because with most providers the fees remain fairly low.
The government subsidy to a provider also varies for public providers outside the
metropolitan areas where the costs of provision are higher in part due to smal er enrolments in any field of study.
As in the other Anglo-American countries, the Australian states, with financial
support from the Australian government, have the major responsibility for funding VET; in contrast to higher education, where the national government has responsibility for the public funding of higher education.
As has already been outlined in the section on funding volumes as well as in this
section above, the share of public funding is comparatively high; this is likely to be an argument in favour of the high participation rates of people aged 40+. Some specific programmes for basic skil provision are presented below in the section on second chance education.
However, this seemingly wel designed and attractive funding regime results in
below average participation rates in adult learning, leaving room for the question, what are the bottlenecks for participation. Furthermore, as mentioned above, one may question whether Australia's sorting in the countries with an established lifelong learning culture is appropriate or whether it should belong to the next group.
Though Austria spends very high shares of its GDP, i.e. 1.3%, participation rates
are comparatively low for such spending figures. Despite the second highest spending per adult (€ 730) its participation rate is close to the European average.
One possible explanation could be that a relatively high share is spent for second
chance education, demanding usual y high amounts per participant. For example, the ‘Adult education initiative' is equipped with € 54.6m to qualify 12,600 adult, which is €
4.330 per adult.55 Another possible explanation is the high spending through the employment agency. However, whether these are the core issues has to be left open; since also Lassnigg et al. (2012) raised concerns about effectiveness of spending, pointing to high spending in relation to participation rate. The country is aiming to reach the 20% benchmark in relation to adult learning participation rates 2020 (LFS).
While second chance education seems to have gained additional attention,
initiatives concerning higher education later if life exist, but address only the examination phase. Instruments for older people do not seem to exist and funding through vouchers etc. is rather limited, possibly not real y supportive in most cases; Upper Austria and Vienna may appear some exceptions.
Another aspect is the probably limited number of beneficiaries of the various
voucher schemes; if our figures are close to reality the average number of beneficiaries per scheme is between 5,500 and 6,600. Given the commonly comparatively high costs of administration of voucher schemes, which is subject to economies of scale, this could suggest to review these lines of funding.
Although responsibility for adult learning in Belgium lies mostly with the regions
(communities), policies are very similar; the federal level is only responsible for the paid training leave. Funding policies operate particularly through supply-side funding, particularly in case of formal and second chance adult learning. Participants have to pay fees, sometimes rather smal amounts, sometimes up to € 400 per course and year; in this regard some differences concerning the maximum amount can be observed. Furthermore, fees may be reimbursed upon successful completion of the programme. Data on funding volumes and participant numbers with regard to the specific target groups are rather limited, 6,665 participants are enrol ed in second chance education in the Flemish region. No specific funding instruments are available for mature students or older people, apart from training leave, time credit regulations and employer-oriented training and guidance vouchers.
With regard to participation rates in general, Belgium has the lowest rates of al
Western European countries showing decreases between AES 2007 and 2011 and time the mean time of instruction decreased from 13 to 8 hours; together with Lithuania it is the only country in Europe showing this pattern.56 This suggests a strong shift in adult learning, which might give room for review and advancement.
In Canada, public financing of adult education is primarily in the areas of literacy,
adult basic education, second (official) language acquisition, and skil s (re)training. Financing of adult education within the post-secondary system (col ege and university)
55 Reviewing spending per beneficiary by state reveals important differences and economies of scale,
i.e. the costs per beneficiary decreases with the number of beneficiaries in a state. This could also suggest to cooperate more in order to decrease costs per beneficiary or to increase the number of beneficiaries.
56 Though Slovenia shows also decreasing Figure s for both indicators, the drop in mean instruction tim
is much smal er.
is not different from financing of youth PSE, except in the case of some skil s training where public funds support some training.
As in other Commonwealth countries, major responsibility is at regional level, which
means that no overarching policy or funding framework exists. The heterogeneity of Canadian funding approaches becomes immediately evident, when reviewing the fol owing Table. The range of instruments is rather broad, while Nunavut applies only the 7 national level instruments; British Columbia adds another 8 provincial instruments to this (the BC TIOW is not counted separately as it is the regional version of the national level TIOW).
Despite the intention of the Canadian education ministers to indicate remarkable
spending levels in their response to UNESCO, it appears questionable whether Canada has a ‘real LLL policy'. Spending levels, even if they may be under-estimated to some extent, would suggest that adult learning for those aged 25+ is not a the core of the Canadian policy.
Denmark's adult learning system is based on an important role of conditional
(performance-based) supply-side funding through the taxameter system (Jespersen 2003). The taxameter system, which covers around 80% of institutional funding, provides block grants to adult learning providers, which are based on a number of criteria and combine input requirements (funding needs) with output orientation, complemented by participant fees as wel as by two overarching grant schemes for individuals, one more for general, one more for vocational adult learning, providing up to € 420 per week – equivalent to 80% of the highest unemployment benefit – for costs of living and for fee payments, if applicable. According to the Ministry of Education these fee payments cover on average 20% of costs and vary between € 15 to 150 per unit, while no fee is demanded for second chance education – this could be considered preferential treatment for this target group. No special (funding) regulations are applied to older/retired people or with regard to mature higher education students; they are treated like any other participant and have access to core funding instruments mentioned above.
Despite the state's comparatively high funding share, employers are the major
financier of adult learning in Denmark, contributing 0.7% of GDP or more than 50%; the training funds are likely to play an important role in this regard (PPMI/FiBS 2012). However, the question arises why this comparatively high funding volume does not result in higher participation rates. This could point to some inefficiencies or ineffectiveness or, alternatively, special conditions preventing higher rates. Compared to other Nordic countries, costs/affordability plays a more important role as obstacle, particularly for women.
According to the indicators established in this study, Estonia seems to be one of the
most effective countries as far as adult learning is concerned, as least if our funding estimates are appropriate. It arrives at above average participation rates, with a spending of around 0.6% of GDP and the lowest spending per adult of al countries (€
130). An explanation for this (seemingly) relatively good result is not immediately identifiable. Although funding seems to be a matter of concern, particularly for females and low-qualified, differences seem comparatively smal ; furthermore, the mean hours of instruction are similar to many other countries. However, state contribution is among the lowest across al countries; less than 20% or only 0.1% of GDP comes from public sources, including employment agency. Furthermore, this funding comes largely from European funding sources.
Interestingly, though, is a relatively high share of mature students in higher
education, which may be due to the particular model of state-based funding for a limited share of (initial higher education) students, which forces al those into other opportunities, and particularly into employment, who cannot afford to pay the high, often ful -cost fees. This model is employed in many newer member states.
France's adult learning system is heavily based on agreements between social
partners and the government, resulting in a strong focus on labour market related training, for employed as wel es unemployed people. The only instrument which is available for non-vocational training are various training leave regulations, whose contribution to participation are rather limited. However, due to the fact that participation rates in adult learning are between 30 and 60% and 70%, respectively, depending on whether age or educational attainment are concerned, France could be an example how a largely employer based funding system arrives at medium level participation rates; according to our national coordinator total spending for CVET arrives at 1.6% of GDP, which would be, though, very high. This could suggest that the system might be somehow ineffective, because several other countries arrive at far higher rates with less money or, vice versa, the same participation rates with lower funding amounts. Furthermore, it appears that private spending is not even yet accounted for. However, it seems that some additional support for certain (under-represented) target groups might be advantageous.
Germany's adult learning system is based on private contributions from individuals
and employers, combined with a (very) limited public role. Around € 600m is spend for (non-vocational) adult learning at Folk high schools and comparable institutions, increasingly based on performance-based supply-side funding; however, the regulations are established by the 16 states and differ much in detail. Public co-funding for individuals is available through one federal scheme (training grant – Bildungsprämie) and various state-level regulations, though commonly restricted to vocational (professional) learning. Non-vocational programmes can be co-financed, if demarcation between vocational and non-vocational learning is blurred, e.g. in case of key competences. Overal , take-up appears relatively limited with up to 150,000, probably, for al voucher schemes; in relation of estimately 5.5m people contributing own means to adult learning. Tax incentives are probably the most important co-funding instrument, fol owed by the master craftsmen loans and grant scheme. This could explain why particularly low-qualified point to costs affordability as obstacle to participation. Furthermore, some evidence exists that the introduction of several
funding instruments of the past 6 to 7 years has not contributed much to increasing participation rates (Dohmen 2013a, 2013b).
Second chance education is also regulated at state level, but three core pathways
across the states exist, (1) evening classes (though they can also be ful -time and are not necessarily restricted to evenings; they are financed through education ministries as part of formal education), (2) through ‘business/technical' col eges, al owing ‘combined' graduation from VET as wel as from formal general education programmes, and (3) so-cal ed vocational preparation programmes of various forms (and not limited to adults but largely for younger people). Al these forms are ful y financed through public means, often in form of conditional supply-side funding, based on demand.
Financing for higher education later in life has been rather limited; only at beginning
of this year 2013 KfW extended its study loan to age 44; previously it was – similar as the law on study support (BAfoeG) limited to age 34. Some special funding is available for older, but not for retired people, though this is restricted to employability and thus considered vocational. Overal participation rates of these target groups are limited, though participation of older people has increased quite a bit compared to previous surveys.
A question is whether the heterogeneity of funding instruments is conducive to
increasing participation rates or whether this discourages particularly the disadvantaged, who may face difficulties in identifying suitable funding opportunities.
Hungary has an AES 2011-participation rate close to the average, which is linked to
total funding of 0.8% of GDP or € 235 per adult. The state contributes one fourth, largely co-funded through ESF. Important to note are the low mean hours of instruction; the figure of 5 hours (AES 2011) is among the lowest of al countries, down from the highest value of 18 in AES 2007. Eventual y, public funding has dropped in Hungary in recent years.
As in other newer member states, the share of mature students in higher education
is comparatively high and also supported by a study loan, open to students up to age 40. Possibly, this share of mature students will increase in the future because of a reduction of state-funded places to 10%.
The Netherlands show some shifts in responsibilities from decentralised to
centralised responsibilities, and backwards again. Overal , funding relies very much on employers and training funds, contributing € 1.7bn in 2008 and € 3bn if labour costs are included (Ministry of Education, Culture and Science 2009), though this figure seems much higher than the CVTS 4-results would suggest. With regard to non-vocational adult learning only some instruments are available, including 2 training leave regulations and several 100% publicly funded instruments, such as supply-side funding and 100% grants; in contrast, it is estimated that 80-90% of adult learning takes place in non-state supported courses and that costs are covered completely by individuals themselves. This could indicate that contributions from individuals in section 4 are
under-estimated. Furthermore, despite public support individuals have to contribute own means to second chance education, which could explain the low take-up rates as identified in section 2.
In general, funding is above 1% of GDP and participation rates are among the top
countries, though information on mean hours of learning is strikingly low – possibly because of mis-reporting. Overal , the Netherlands appear to be doing quite wel , despite comparatively limited state funding in several indicators, as reported in section 4 which is compensated by employer funding of at least 0.7% of GDP, which is highest together with Denmark.57
Norway combines national, county and local responsibilities: The Ministry of
Education and Research is responsible for the administration of the statutory educational provisions of the Education Act as well as for developing curriculum guidelines. This Act also gives the regulations for formal primary and secondary education for children, youth and adults. The Ministry is also responsible for the administration of the Adult Education Act (2009). The municipalities are responsible for the implementing of formal adult education at primary and lower secondary level as wel as for adult immigrants of Norwegian as a second language. The counties are responsible for the implementation of formal adult education at upper secondary level. The public authorities cooperate with study associations representing non-governmental organisations.
Though the state is involved in the financing of adult learning, specific regulations
depend on the municipalities, receiving lump-sum block grants from the national level for al formal education sector and are free to al ocate them as they seem fit. Overal , average spending per adult in Norway is € 925 per annum; which is € 200 more than the next country. Costs per beneficiary are € 2,000; though breakdown by programme is not possible. The state's contribution of 0.6% of GDP is the highest across al countries in this study.
Romania has the lowest participation rate of al countries and by far the highest
share of non-participants pointing to costs and affordability as obstacle; more than 50% of non-participants mention this aspect and even two thirds among the low-qualified. The chance of highly educated adults to participate in adult learning is 16-times higher than for low-qualified.
Furthermore, almost no data on funding volumes seems available. The only figure
we could gather during this study suggests a public spending of € 18m by the employment agency; this would amount to slightly more than € 3 per adult. This would be by far the lowest public spending Figure across al countries.
57 If MOE Figure s are more appropriate than CVTS 4-data on employer spending the Figure would even
According to the country brief it appears that no other (public) funding for adult
learning is available, although the country changed its law, which is now ‘dedicated to the principle of lifelong learning'. It will have to be seen whether this is supportive to increase spending for adult learning; the results of this study suggest an urgent need to provide public funding also to employed people, actual y public funding is focused on unemployed and companies. A recent study on financing training provides some indication that support for employers may not be very conducive to support the participation adult learning (PPMI/FiBS 2012), particularly not with regard to those people more in need of support, even though employers in Romania contribute probably between 0.4 and 0.5% of GDP.58
Slovakia has a strong focus on employers, for which comparatively many funding
instruments are available (PPMI/FiBS 2012), while only very little supply-side funding supports adult learners directly, whereas training leave regulations address time constraints. Consequently, employers bear by far the biggest share, while contribution from the state and individuals is rather limited, whatsoever indicator presented in this study is concerned.
Slovenia has had comparatively high and above average participation rate in adult
learning in the past; ranging within the top third in both surveys (LFS and AES 2007). However, in recent years participation rates dropped, despite stil considerable – though decreasing – funding for adult learning. Almost 1.0% of GDP was spent in 2011, which is the highest figure among newer member states and largely based on employers' and individual contributions. Only 0.2% of GDP is spent from public and EU sources. Despite the comparatively high overal spending figures, spending per adult is only € 365, which is, though, stil the highest value among the newer member states.
The country's core focus is on initial education and funding for adult learning, i.e. the
focus lies with disadvantaged groups, i.e. low-skil ed/qualified. Reviewing the limited public spending in relation to participation, this could suggest a relatively effective system, where deadweight loss of public spending is comparatively limited; however, this would require further investigation. In contrast, the overal result seems less promising as the spending per adult is quite high in relation to its participation rate; some countries with lower overall spending per adult (SK, EE) reveal higher participation rates than Slovenia.
Spain shows a contradictory picture. While the country has below average
participation rates according to AES 2007 and 2011, it LFS figures are above EU average, suggesting comparatively high mean hours of instruction, likely due to formal adult education. The high mean hours of instruction are confirmed, when reviewing Figure 1, Spain has among the highest values and is the only country, where an increase in participation is not linked to reduced mean hours of instruction.
58 No figure on company spending is provided by CVTS 4; this figure is based on CVTS 3-data.
Additionally, no spending figure is available for individuals from AES 2007; therefore, Romania is not included in the funding amount estimates in section 4.
Interestingly, this seems to be linked to comparatively little funding for adult learning of around 0.5% of GDP. This could raise questions on how to increase participation rates, particularly when looking at the high unemployment rates, even if the often stated rate of 50% and above does not seem to provide the correct picture. In relation to spending per adult, Spain belongs to a group at the lower ends; among those countries for which this study was able to estimate funding figures, only Estonia spends less.59 However, Spain spending indicators are comparable to other countries with similar participation rates.
Another point, which is at the margin of this study, is that employer spending seems
comparatively limited, despite the existence of a national training fund. While employer spending in many countries is above 1% of the payrol , it is only 0.8% in Spain. This results in a Figure of 0.3% of GPD, which is among the lowest employer funding rates across al countries.
The United Kingdom has a long tradition of adult learning including both personal
development and more vocational y orientated learning, though recently with a particular focus on (employability oriented) social inclusion and employability, i.e. adult learning is particularly oriented towards the labour market. However, some funding (£210m; € 260m) also available for more general learning. With regard to participation rates, the UK has experienced strong reductions in LFS figures in recent years, down from 19.4 to 15.6% between 2010 and 2011. Very recently published data for AES 2011 point to the same direction; while participation rate was 49.3% in 2007, it is only 35.8% in 2011.
Several funding sources are available to support private investment in adult
learning, including for higher education, e.g. through interest-subsidised loans (Personal and Career Development Loan and the same loan scheme than for younger students). However, Cal endar (2013) points to important and disadvantages changes for part-time students, which is the bulk of mature students, in the light of the recent changes in higher education funding, which may affect their participation in higher education. Institutional support is available for second chance education (supply-side funding), though not much complemented through special support for individuals, apart from maintenance grants of £30 per week for certain groups – instead, individuals may have to contribute to institutional costs in some cases – , as well as for older people through financing of so-cal ed Universities of Third Age and/or community learning.
Of importance is the complete overhaul of the funding system for adult learning,
which will almost entirely consist of (income-contingent) "Advanced Learning Loans" from August 2013 onwards; the only exception concerns those who left compulsory education without attaining the necessary literacy and numeracy skil s for employability. The expectation is that demand is 50,000 in the first and 160,000 in the second year;
59 For completeness, it might be the case that spending Figure s are underreported, because spending
of only € 6.1m from employment agency seems rather low.
experts are sceptical that these figures wil be reached (Fletcher 2011). Of utmost interest is whether this shift will be able to increase participation rates in adult learning in the (near) future; it would not be surprising if the opposite would be the case.
The United States of America have a strong focus on higher education as part of
their adult learning system, for which the bulk of funding sources is available, while, in contrast, public funding for non-university adult learning seems rather limited (0.1% of GDP). Furthermore, non-vocational adult learning is considered private responsibility, for which no public funding is provided; some employer sponsoring might be available though.
In spite of this rather limited public funding, funding levels for adult learning appear
to be remarkably high compared to al other countries, if the ASTD-estimate on employer spending for company-related training is realistic, whereas another estimate by Wilson (2010) would result in below average spending for adult learning. In this latter case, the US participation rate would appear comparatively high, while the higher amounts would better fit with the overal pattern, identified in this study.60
The policy with regard to (non-vocational) adult learning rests on the one hand on a
Federal-States-Localities responsibility with State matching and maintenance; at state level federal y provided funds are distributed on a competitive basis to local providers.
60 However, there is no additional evidence that the spending volumes are as high as the ASTD-estimate
suggests, except the better fit into the overal pattern.
Bibliography
Bassanini, A. Alison Booth, Maria de Paulo, Edwin Leuven (2006), Workplace Training in
Brunel o, Giorgio (2001), On the Complementarity between Education and Training in Europe,
IZA-Discussion Paper, No. 309, IZA - Institute for the Study of Labor, Bonn.
Brunel o, Giorgio, Simona Comi, Daniela Sonedda (2010) Training Subsidies and the Wage
Returns to Continuing Vocational Training: Evidence from Italian Regions, IZA Discussion
Callender, Claire (2013), Part-Time Undergraduate Student Funding and Financial Support, in:
Claire Callender, Peter Scott (eds), Browne and beyond: Modernizing English Higher Education, London (forthcoming).
Cedefop (2009), Using tax incentives to promote education and training. Panorama Series,
Cedefop (2011), The anatomy of the wider benefits of VET in the workplace, Research Paper
No. 12, Thessaloniki.
Cedefop (2012a), Training leave. Policies and practices in Europe, Research Paper No. 28,
Cedefop (2012b), Payback clauses in Europe. Supporting company investment in training,
Cedefop (2012c), Learning and innovation in companies, Research paper No. 27, Luxembourg.
Connolly, Mark, Gareth Rees, Cerys Furlong (2008), The Wider Benefits of Adult Learning,
Llywodraeth Cynul iad Cymru Welsh Assembly Government, NIACE Dysgu Cymru, Cardiff School of Social Sciences, Cardiff University.
Coulombe, Serge, Jean-François Tremblay, Sylvie Marchand (2004), Literacy scores, human
capi-tal and growth across fourteen OECD countries, Statistics Canada, Canada.
Coelli, Michael B., Domenico Tabasso, Rezida Zakirova (2012), Studying beyond age 25: who
does it and what do they gain?, National Centre for Vocational Education Research (NCVER) Re-search Report, Melbourne, Australia: Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research.
Dohmen, Dieter (1999), Finanzbedarf und Verteilungswirkungen des kombinierten
Finanzierungsmodel s: Bildungssparen, Bildungsgutscheine und Bildungsdarlehen. Gutachten für den Sachverständigenrat Bildung bei der Hans-Böckler-Stiftung, FiBS-Forum Nr. 1, Forschungsinstitut für Bildungs- und Sozialökonomie, Berlin (URL: http://www.fibs.eu).
Dohmen, Dieter (2007), Current Trends in the demand-led financing of further training in Europe
– A synopsis, FiBS-Forum Nr. 40, Berlin (URL: www.fibs.eu).
Dohmen, Dieter (2009), Bildungskonten und Steueranreize – ein internationaler Überblick, in:
VÖGB/AK Wien Veranstaltungsreihe "Chance Weiterbildung", 2008/2009 – Tagungsband, Wien.
Dohmen, Dieter (2010), Bildungsgutscheine zwischen Theorie und Praxis, in: Heiner Barz (ed.),
Handbuch Bildungsfinanzierung, Wiesbaden.
Dohmen, Dieter (2013a), Deutschlands Weiterbildungsfinanzierung im internationalen
Vergleich, DIE-Trends der Weiterbildung 2013, Bielefeld, (i.V.)
Dohmen, Dieter (2013b), Finanzierung beruflicher und betrieblicher Weiterbildung in
Deutschland, Weiterbildungsreport Nr. 3, (i.V.)
Dohmen, Dieter, Rocio Ramirez-Rodriguez (2010), Aktuel e Trends der nachfrageorientierten
Weiterbildungsfinanzierung in Europa, Gutachten im Auftrag des Deutschen Instituts für Erwachsenenbildung, Berlin.
Eurydice (2013), Funding of Education in Europe. The Impact of the Economic Crisis, Brussels.
Falch, Torberg, Hessel Oosterbeek (2011), Financing lifelong learning: Funding mechanisms in
education and training, EENEE Analytical report No. 10, prepared for the European Commission, Munich.
Feinstein, Leon (2002a), Quantitative Estimates of the Social Benefits of Learning, 1: Crime,
Research Report No.5, Centre for Research on the Wider Benefits of Learning, London.
Feinstein, Leon (2002b), Quantitative Estimates of the Social Benefits of Learning, 2: Health
(depression and obesity), Research Report No.6, Centre for Research on the Wider Benefits of Learning, London.
Feinstein, Leon, Cathie Hammond (2004), The contribution of adult learning to health and social
capital, Wider Benefits of Learning, Research Report No. 8., Institute of Education, London.
Feinstein, Leon, Arnaud Chevalier (2006), Sheepskin or Prozac: The Causal Effect of Education
on Mental Health, IZA Discussion Papers 2231, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).
Feinstein, Leon, Cathie Hammond (2004), The contribution of adult learning to health and social
capital, Wider Benefits of Learning, Research Report No. 8., Institute of Education, London.
Feinstein, Leon, Ricardo Sabates (2007), The Public Value of Adult Learning: skil s and social
productivity, mimeo.
Field, John (2012), Is lifelong learning making the difference?, in: Aspin, David, Judith
Chapman, Karen Evans, Richard Bagnall (eds.), Second International Handbook of Lifelong Learning, Springer, Dordrecht, pp. 887-897.
Hansson, Bo (2008), Job-related training and benefits for individuals: a reivew of evidence and
explanations, OECD Education Working Paper No. 19, Paris.
Heckman, James J., (2013), Auf die Familie kommt es an, in: DIE ZEIT, 20.6.2013 Nr. 26 (URL:
Jenkins, A. (2006). Women, lifelong learning and transitions into employment, in: Work,
Employment and Society, 20(2), pp. 306-328.
Jenkins, A., A. Vignoles, A. Wolfe, F. Galindo Rueda (2003), The determinants and labour
market effects of lifelong learning, in: Applied Economics, 35, pp. 1711-1721.
Kruppe, Thomas (2012), Effectiveness of further vocational learning in Germany, IAB-
Discussion Paper, No. 10/12, Nuremberg.
Lassnigg, Lorenz, Stefan Vogtenhuber, Ingrid Osterhaus (2013), Finanzierung von
Erwachsenen- und Weiterbildung in Österreich und in ausgewählten Vergleichsländern. Strategische Überlegungen (Financing of Adult and Further Education in Austria and selected comparison countries. Strategic considerations), Research Report, Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna.
Leuven, Edwin, Hessel Oosterbeek (2004), Evaluating the effect of tax deductions on training,
Journal of Labour Economics, Vol. 22, pp. 461-488.
Lynch, Lisa M. (1994), Training And the Private Sector, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Manninen, Jyri (2010), Wider benefits of Learning within Liberal Adult Education and Training,
University of Eastern Finland, Joensuu.
Manninen, Jyri (2012), Wider benefits of liberal adult education, University of Eastern Finland
Manninen, Jyri (2013), Wider benefits' freier Erwachsenenbildung, in: DIE Magazin, 1/2013, pp.
Messer, Dolores, Guido Schwerdt., Ludger Woessmann, Stefan C. Wolter (2010). Labor market
effects of adult education vouchers: Evidence from a randomized field experiment. Working paper (mimeo).
Motschilnig, Ricarda (2012), Wider Benefits of Adult Learning – An Inventory of Existing Studies
and Research, in: Adult Education and Development, No. 78, Institut für Internationale Zusammenarbeit des Deutschen Volkshochschul-Verbandes (ed.) (www.iiz-dvv.de/index.php? article_id=1321&clang=1).
Murray, Asa, Aners Skarlind (2005), Was bringt eine Berufsausbildung jungen Erwachsenen am
Arbeitsmarkt?, in: Berufsbildung Nr. 34, p. 18-31).
Wolter, Stefan C., Dolores Messer (2009), Weiterbildung und Bildungsgutscheine – Resultate
aus einem experimentel en Feldversuch, Forschungsstelle für Bildungsökonomie an der Universität Bern in Zusammenarbeit mit dem Bundesamt für Statistik, Schweiz. Studie im Auftrag des Bundesamtes für Berufsbildung und Technologie, Schweiz.
OECD (2004), OECD Employment Outlook 2004, – Improving Skil s for More and Better Jobs:
Does Training Make a Difference. Paris.
OECD (2008), Education at a Glance, Paris.
OECD (2012), Education at a Glance, Paris.
Oosterbeek; Hessel (2013), The financing of adult learning, EENEE Analytical Report, No. 15,
prepared for the European Commission.
PPMI, FiBS (2012, Financing Training in Europe, Study commissioned by CEDEFOP, Final
Statistisches Bundesamt/Federal Office of Statistics (2012), Ausbildungsförderung nach dem
Aufstiegsfortbildungsförderungsgesetzt (AFBG) 2011, Wiesbaden.
Wößmann, Ludger (2013), Wer vier Jahre studiert, verdient 40 Prozent mehr, in: Süddeutsche
Zhang, Xuelin, Boris Palameta (2006), Participation in Adult Schooling and its Earnings Impact
in Canada, Statistics Canada, Ottawa.
List of abbreviations
AL – Adult Learning
AES – Adult Education Survey
AES/OECD 2007 – Adult learning participation rates with data retrieved from AES 2007 and
complemented by data for 2007 from OECD (2012) for the non-European countries
ASTD – American Society of Training and Development BSP – Basic Skil Provision CVET – Continuing Vocational and Educational Training ECTS – European Credit Transfer System Eds. – Editors EEA – European Economic Area EFRD – European Fund for Regional Development ET – European Cooperation in Education and Training EUA – Association of European Institutions of Higher Education FCE – Full-country Equivalent FED – Formal Adult Learning FE – Fixed Effects GDP – Gross Domestic Product HE – Higher Education HEI – Higher Education Institution HR – Human Resources ICT – Information and Communication Technology ILA – Individual Learning Accounts ISCED – International Standard Classification of Education LFS – Labour Force Survey LLL – Lifelong Learning LLP – Lifelong Learning Programme NFE – Non-formal Adult Learning NGO – Non-governmental Organization PCDL – Personal and Career Development Loan POLS – Pooled Ordinary Least Squares PPS – Purchasing Power Standard PTL – Paid training leave R&D – Research and Development RE – Random effects SCE – Second Chance Education TL – Training leave UTP – Unpaid training leave SME – Smal and Medium Enterprises VET – Vocational Education and Training WTA – Wil ingness to Accept WTP – Wil ingness to Pay
Glossary
Adult learning – learning activities of adults, aged 25 and older, after leaving initial
AES/OECD 2007 – Adult learning participation rates with data retrieved from AES 2007 and
complemented by data for 2007 from OECD (2012) for the non-European countries
Deadweight loss – measures the share of public subsidies, not resulting in additional
participation in adult learning, because people are subsidised who would have paid for adult learning themselves if no public support would have been available
Internal rates of return – measure the returns to an investment, here education,
comparable to interest rates, i.e. what would have been the interest rate for a similar capital investment
Market failure – refers to situations in which the market does not result in the optimal
Mapping survey – survey conducted for this study, providing an overview on funding
instruments in a country and prepared by national expert
Policy briefs – short and summarised overview on adult learning policy in a country,
prepared especial y for this study by national expert
Windfal profits – benefit for beneficiaries of public subsidies, who would have paid for
adult learning themselves if no public support would have been available
Research team
FiBS
Dr. Dieter Dohmen
Birgitt A. Cleuvers
Anke Schulz
DIE
Dr. Dieter Gnahs
Carolin Knauber
Panteia
Bert-Jan Buiskook
Simon Broek
Peter Henk Eshuis
National experts
Australia: Gerald Burke, former Director of the Center for the Economics of Education
and Training, Monash University
Austria: Michael Töl e, Chamber of Labour, Vienna Belgium: Barbara Vandeweghe, Daphne Valsamis, Idea Consult Canada: Brigid Hayes, independent Consultant Denmark: Jorgen Ole Larsen, Metropolitan University Col ege Estonia: Kal e Toom, Ministry of Education Germany: Dieter Dohmen (FiBS), Dieter Gnahs (DIE) Hungary: Eva Farkas, University of Szeged, independent consultant Italy: Cristina Brecciaroli, independent consultant Netherlands: Simon Broek, Panteia Norway: Anne Skomedal, Ministry of Education Romania: Razvan Ionut Cirica, independent consultant Slovakia: Juraj Vantuch, independent consultant Slovenia: Peter Beltram, Slovenian Institute for Adult Education Spain: Pedro J. Perez, University of Valencia Switzerland: Andre Schläfli, Schweizerischer Verband für Weiterbildung United Kingdom: Nicholas Fox, The Individual Learning Company USA: Johan Uvin, Department for Education
Source: http://arhiv.acs.si/porocila/Financing_the_Adult_Learning_Sector-final_report.pdf
Social Science & Medicine 55 (2002) 1325–1336 Researching sexual and reproductive behaviour: a peer ethnographic approach Neil Price*, Kirstan Hawkins1 Centre for Development Studies, University of Wales, Swansea SA2 8PP, UK In recent years, ethnographic research has challenged the notion within demography that fertility-related behaviour is the outcome of individualistic calculations of the costs and benefits of having children. Anthropology has furthercriticised the abstraction in demographic analysis of sexual behaviour and fertility decision-making from the socio-cultural and political context in which the individual or couple is located. Within demography itself, institutional andpolitical-economic analyses have argued strongly that sexual and reproductive behaviour must be understood withinlocally specific social, cultural, economic and political contexts. Positivist and empiricist research methods, such as thesample survey and focus groups, which continue to dominate demographic inquiry and applied research into sexual andreproductive behaviour, have been shown to be limited in their ability to inform about the process of behaviour changeand contexts within which different behaviours occur. The article introduces a new methodology for researching sexualand reproductive behaviour, called the peer ethnographic approach, which the authors have developed in an attempt toaddress some of the limitations of the methods which currently dominate research into sexual and reproductivebehaviour. The peer ethnographic methodology is discussed in detail and the results of recent field-testing are reported,which show that, although the approach has limitations, it also has the potential to make a significant contribution toour understanding of sexual and reproductive behaviour. r 2002 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.
Pharmacoepidemiological Research on Outcomes of Therapeutics by a European ConsorTium IMI Work Package 5: Report 2:b:ii Benefit - Risk Wave 2 Case Study Report: Rosiglitazone Benefit-Risk Analysis Lawrence Phillips, Billy Amzal, Alex Asiimwe, Edmond Chan, Chen Chen, Diana Hughes, Juhaeri Juhaeri, Alain Micaleff, Shahrul Mt-Isa, Becky Noel, Susan Shepherd, Nan Wang On behalf of PROTECT Work Package 5 participants